Arhan S. Ertan, Louis Putterman
Abstract Existing research in the area of economic growth suggests that the era of colonization has had an impact upon the modern levels of economic development of countries around the globe. However, why some countries were colonized early, some late, and others not at all, and what effect these differences have on current national income, has not been studied systematically. In the first part of this paper, we show that both the occurrence and timing of colonization can be explained by (a) differences in levels of pre-1500 development associated with different dates of transition to agriculture (Neolithic revolution) and with the associated history of state-level polities, (b) geographic proximity to the colonizing powers, and (c) the disease environment faced by the colonizers. In the second part, we analyze the developmental consequences of colonization taking the endogeneity of colonizations occurrence and timing into account. We find evidence that history of colonization does not have a direct affect on recent levels of income and recent rates of economic growth. But we also find that the share of the population that migrated from the places of greater pre-modern development had a positive impact both on current level and growth rate of income and on the quality of institutions in the newly settled places. Thus we conclude that the positive effect of colonization on current development works largely through the impact on the quality of institutions of the pre-colonial development levels of the ancestors of current populations.
JEL Classification: O11, O13, O40, O57 Keywords: Colonization, Economic Growth, Institutions, Pre-Modern Development, Migration.
Determinants and Economic Consequences of Colonization: A Global Analysis
“The discovery of America and that of a passage to the East Indies by the Cape of Good Hope are the two greatest and most
References: [1] Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. (2001). “The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation”, American Economic Review 91 (5), 1369-1401. [2] Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. (2002). “Reversal of fortunes: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 1231-1294. [3] Albouy, David (2004). “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data”, unpublished paper, University of California, Berkeley. [4] Bertocchi, Graziella and Fabio Canova (2002). “Did Colonization Matter for Growth? An Empirical Exploration into the Historical Causes of Africa’s Underdevelopment”, European Economic Review, XLVI, 1851-1871. [5] Bockstette, Valerie, Areendam Chanda and Louis Putterman (2002). “States and Markets: The Advantage of an Early Start”, Journal of Economic Growth 7: 347-69. [6] Boserup, Ester (1965). “Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agricultural Change Under Population Pressure”, New York: Aldine. [7] Burkett, John P., Catherine Humblet and Louis Putterman (1999). “Pre-Industrial and PostWar Economic Development: Is There a Link?”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 47 (3): 471-95. [8] Chanda, Areendam and Louis Putterman (forthcoming). “Early Starts, Reversals and Catch-up in the Process of Economic Development”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics. [9] Davidson, R. and J. G. MacKinnon (1993). “Estimation and Inference in Econometrics”, 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press. [10] Diamond, J. (1997). “Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies.” Norton, New York. [11] Easterly, W., Levine, R. (2003). “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development.”, Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 3-39. 31 [12] Galor, O., Weil, D. (2000). “Population, technology, and growth: From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition and beyond.”, American Economic Review 90 (4), 806-828. [13] Galor, O., Moav, O. (2002). “Natural selection and the origin of economic growth.”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 1133-1192. [14] Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and, Andrei Shleifer, (2004). “Do Institutions Cause Growth?”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10568. [15] Goodfriend, M., McDermott, J. (1995). “Early Development”, American Economic Review 85, 116-133. [16] Grier, Robin, (1999). “Colonial Legacies and Economic Growth”, Public Choice 98, 317-335. [17] Hall, R., Jones, C. (1999). “Why do some countries produce so much more output than others?”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1), 83-116. [18] Hausman, J. (1978). “Specification tests in econometrics”, Econometrica 46(6): 1251-1271. [19] Hibbs, Douglas A., and Ola Olsson, 2004, “Geography, biogeography, and why some countries are rich and others are poor”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 101: 3715-3720. [20] Hibbs, Douglas A., and Ola Olsson (2005). “Biogeography and Long-Run Economic Development”, European Economic Review, 49: 909-938. [21] Kiszewski A., A. Mellinger, P. Malaney. A.Spielman, S.Ehrlich and J.D. Sachs (2004). “A Global Index of the Stability of Malaria Transmission Based on the Intrinsic Properties of Anopheline Mosquito Vectors”, American Journal of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene (forthcoming). [22] Knack, S. and P. Keefer (1995). “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures”, Economics and Politics 7(3): 207-225. [23] Kremer, M. (1993). “Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3), 681-716. [24] La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, Vishny (1999). “The Quality of Government”, The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 15 (1), 222-279. 32 [25] La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny (1998). “Law and Finance”, Journal of Political Economy 106(6), 1113-1155. [26] Landes, David S. (1998). The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some are so Rich and Some so Poor. New York: Norton. [27] Mauro, P. (1995). “Corruption and Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681-712. [28] McEvedy, C. and R. Jones (1978). Atlas of World Population History, Viking Press. [29] North, D. (1981). Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton. [30] North, Douglas C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press. [31] North, Summerhill and Weingast (2000). “Order, Disorder and Economic Change: Latin America versus North America”, in: Mesquita and Root, eds., Governing for Prosperity. New Haven: Yale University Press. [32] Putterman, Louis (2004). “State Antiquity Index Version 3”, available at http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/Louis Putterman/ [33] Putterman, Louis (2006). “World Migration Matrix, 1500 - 2000”, available at http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/Louis Putterman/ [34] Putterman, Louis, with Cary Anne Trainor (2006). “Agricultural Transition Year Country Data Set”, available at http://www.econ.brown.edu/fac/Louis Putterman. [35] Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., Trebbi, F. (2002). “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development.”, Working Paper No. 9305, NBER, Cambridge, MA. [36] Sokoloff, Kenneth and Stanley Engermann (2000). “Institutions, Factor Endowments and Paths to Development in the New World”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 217-232. [37] Wooldridge, J. (2002). “Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach”, 2nd ed. New York: South-Western College Publishing. 33 [38] Wu, D. M. (1973). “Alternative Tests of Independence Between Stochastic Regressors and Disturbances”, Econometrica 41(4): 733-750. 34