One of the myths of executive compensation is that the most effective way to motivate people to work productively is through individual incentive compensation (Pfeffer, 1998). While most people agree that money cannot buy everything, in organizations there is a widespread belief that money plays a major role in motivating people. Organizations spend a lot of time, effort and money in designing and implementing the right performance management schemes and incentive schemes to motivate their executives. It is accepted as a matter of fact that if only we could measure desirable behaviors and reward individuals commensurate with their results then all our motivational problems would be solved. But what is the truth of this statement? Are monetary rewards and incentive systems a panacea for all motivational issues? While money may definitely help attract and retain talented people, we have reason to believe that monetary incentive schemes may also have some undesirable effects on morale of employees. Kohn (1993) argues that monetary rewards only secure temporary compliance and do not build any long term commitment or lasting behavioral changes in people. According to Meyer (1975) the basis for most of the problems with merit pay plans is that most people think their own performance is above average. Since no plan can give a positive feedback to all persons, it threatens the self-esteem of individuals. People cope with this by demeaning the importance of the job or by derogating the source of the reward. This paper explores the origins of our belief in the motivating power of money and some of the undesirable effects of monetary incentive schemes for executives. We start by trying to understand some of the fundamental assumptions which make us believe that money is a motivator, then we look at some objective evidence on the motivational power of money and finally we focus on some of the dysfunctional effects of relying on money as a
References: Amabile, T. M. (1988). A model of creativity and innovation in organizations. In B. M. Staw and L. L. Cummings (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior, Vol. 10, 123-167. JAI Press. Baker, G. P., Jensen, M.C., & Murphy, K. J. (1988). Compensation and incentives: practice vs. theory. Journal of Finance, 43, 593-616. Besser, T. L. (1995). Reward and organizational goal achievement: A case study of Toyota Motor manufacturing in Kentucky. Journal of Management Studies, 32, 383-400. Condry, I. (1977). Enemies of exploration: Self-initiated versus other-initiated learning. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 459-477. Cowherd, C. M., & Levine, D. I. (1992). Product quality and pay equity between lower-level employees and top management: An investigation of distributive justice theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 302-321. Deci, E. L. (1971). Effects of externally mediated rewards on intrinsic motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 18, 105-115. Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., & Sutton, R. L. (2005). Economics language and assumptions: How theories can become self-fulfilling. Academy of Management Review, 30. 8-24. Ghoshal, S. (2005). Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning and Education, 4, 75-91. Ghoshal, S. & Moran, P. (1996). Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21, 13-47. Hackman, J. R., & Oldham, G. R. (1976). Motivation through the design of work. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16, 250-279. 11 Kerr, S. (1975). On the folly of rewarding A while hoping for B. Academy of Management Journal, 18, 769-783. Kohn, A., (1993). Why incentive plans cannot work. Harvard Business Review, SeptemberOctober, 1-7. Krishnan, V.R. 2003. Do business schools change students’ values along desirable lines? A longitudinal study, In S.M. Natale and A.F. Libertella (eds) Business education and training: A value-laden process, Volume 8 (Immortal Longings), pp. 26-39. University Press of America, Lanham. Liberman, V., Samuels, S., & Ross, L. (2004). The name of the game: Predictive power of reputation vs. situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30, 1175-1185. Meyer, H. H. (1975). The Pay-for-Performance Dilemma. Organizational Dynamics, 3, 3950. Miller, D. T., & Ratner, R. K. (1998). The disparity between the actual and assumed power of self-interest. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 74, 53-62. Opsahl, K. L., & Dunnette, M. D. (1966). The role of financial compensation in industrial motivation, Psychological Bulletin, 66, 94-118. Pfeffer, J. (1998). Six dangerous myths about pay. Harvard Business Review, 76, 109-119. Pittman, T. S., Emery, J., & Boggiano, A. K. (1982). Intrinsic and extrinsic motivational orientations: Reward-induced changes in preference for complexity. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 42, 789-797. Shamir, B. (1991). Meaning, self and motivation in organizations. Organization Studies, 12, 405-424. Simon, H.A. (1945). Administrative Behavior, New York: The Macmillan Company. 12 Singh, N., & Krishnan, V. R. (2005). Towards understanding transformational leadership in India: A grounded theory approach. Vision: The Journal of Business Perspective, 9, 517. Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won-b5-c1-article-1-ss3.htm Retrieved August 26, 2005. Vroom, V. H. (1964). Work and motivation. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers. Williamson, O. E. (1964). The economics of discretionary behavior: Managerial objectives in a theory of the firm. Prentice-Hall Inc. Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications: A study in the economics of internal organization. New York: Free Press. 13