Top-Rated Free Essay
Preview

Mujo Kuje Konja Po Mjesecu

Best Essays
2798 Words
Grammar
Grammar
Plagiarism
Plagiarism
Writing
Writing
Score
Score
Mujo Kuje Konja Po Mjesecu
Institutions Matter, but Not for Everything
The role of geography and resource endowments in development shouldn’t be underestimated
Jeffrey D. Sachs
HE DEBATE over the role of institutions in economic development has become dangerously simplified. The vague concept of “institutions” has become, almost tautologically, the intermediate target for all efforts to improve an economy. If an economy is malfunctioning, the reasoning goes, something must be wrong with its institutions. In fact, recent papers have argued that institutions explain nearly everything about a country’s level of economic development and that resource constraints, physical geography, economic policies, geopolitics, and other aspects of internal social structure, such as gender roles and inequalities between ethnic groups, have little or no effect. These papers have been written by such respected economists as Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson; Dani Rodrik, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi; and William Easterly and Ross Levine. Indeed, a single-factor explanation of something as important as economic development can be alluring, and the institutions-only argument has special allure for two additional reasons. First, it attributes high income levels in the United States, Europe, and Japan to allegedly superior social institutions; it even asserts that when incomes rise in other regions, they do so mainly because of the Western messages of freedom, property rights, and markets carried there by intrepid missionaries intent on economic development. Second, according to the argument, the rich world has little, if any, financial responsibility for the poor because development failures are the result of institutional failures and not of a lack of resources. The problem is that the evidence simply does not support those conclusions. Institutions may matter, but they don’t matter exclusively. The barriers to economic development in the poorest countries today are far more complex than insti-

T

tutional shortcomings. Rather than focus on improving institutions in sub-Saharan Africa, it would be wise to devote more effort to fighting AIDS, tuberculosis, and malaria; addressing the depletion of soil nutrients; and building more roads to connect remote populations to regional markets and coastal ports. In other words, sub-Saharan Africa and other regions struggling today for improved economic development require much more than lectures about good governance and institutions. They require direct interventions, backed by expanded donor assistance, to address disease, geographical isolation, low technological productivity, and resource limitations that trap them in poverty. Good governance and sound institutions would, no doubt, make such interventions more effective.

When economic growth fails When Adam Smith, our profession’s original and wisest champion of sound economic institutions, turned his eye to the poorest parts of the world in 1776, he did not so much as mention institutions in explaining their woes. It is worth quoting at length from Smith’s Wealth of Nations on the plight of sub-Saharan Africa and central Asia, which remain the world’s most troubled development hot spots:
All the inland parts of Africa, and all that part of Asia which lies any considerable way north of the Euxine and Caspian seas, the ancient Scythia, the modern Tartary and Siberia, seem in all ages of the world to have been in the same barbarous and uncivilised state in which we find them at present. The Sea of Tartary is the frozen ocean which admits of no navigation, and though some of the greatest rivers in the world run through that country, they are at too great a distance from one another to carry commerce

38

Finance & Development June 2003

and communication through the greater part of it. There are in Africa none of those great inlets, such as the Baltic and Adriatic seas in Europe, the Mediterranean and Euxine seas in both Europe and Asia, and the gulfs of Arabia, Persia, India, Bengal, and Siam, in Asia, to carry maritime commerce into the interior parts of that great continent: and the great rivers of Africa are at too great a distance from one another to give occasion to any considerable inland navigation. (Book I, Chapter III) Smith’s point is that Africa and central Asia could not effectively participate in international trade because transport costs were simply too high. And, without international trade, both regions were condemned to small internal markets, an inefficient division of labor, and continued poverty. These disadvantages of the hinterland exist to this day. Smith couldn’t know the half of it. The problems of African isolation went far beyond mere transport costs. Characterized by the most adverse malaria ecology in the world, Africa was as effectively cut off from global trade and investment by that killer disease. Although the disease ecology of malaria was not understood properly until two centuries after Adam Smith, what was known demonstrated that Africa’s suffering was unique. It had a climate conducive to year-round transmission of malaria and was home to a species of mosquito ideally suited to transmitting malaria from person to person. When Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson find that the high mortality rates of British soldiers around 1820 in various parts of the world correlate well with the low levels of GNP per capita in the 1990s, they are discovering the pernicious effects of malaria in blocking longterm economic development. The ability of a disease to cut off economic development may seem surprising to some but reflects a lack of understanding of how disease can affect economic performance. Thus, in writing that malaria has a limited impact in sub-Saharan Africa because most adults have some acquired immunity, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson completely neglect the fact that the disease dramatically lowers the returns on foreign investments and raises the transaction costs of international trade, migration, and tourism in malarial regions. This is like claiming that the effects of the recent SARS (Severe Acute Respiratory Syndrome) outbreak in Hong Kong SAR can be measured by the number of deaths so far attributable to the disease rather than by the severe disruption in travel to and from Asia. In an environment in which capital and people can move around with relative ease, the disadvantages of adverse geo-

The ability of a disease to cut off economic development may seem surprising to some but reflects a lack of understanding of how disease can affect economic performance.

graphy—physical isolation, endemic disease, or other local problems (such as poor soil fertility)—are magnified. It is probably true that when human capital is high enough in any location, physical capital will flow in as a complementary factor of production. Skilled workers can sell their outputs to world markets almost anywhere, over the Internet or by plane transport. Landlocked and at a high altitude, Denver can still serve as a high-tech hub of tourism, trade, and information technology. But when countries that are remote or have other problems related to their geography also have few skilled workers, these workers are much more likely to emigrate than to attract physical capital into the country. This is true even of geographically remote regions within countries. For example, China is having great difficulty attracting investments into its western provinces and is instead facing a massive shift of labor, including the west’s few skilled workers, to the eastern and coastal provinces. Recent history, then, confirms Smith’s remarkable insights. Good institutions certainly matter, and bad institutions can sound the death knell of development even in favorable environments. But poor physical endowments may also hamper development. During the globalization of the past 20 years, economic performance has diverged markedly in the developing world, with countries falling into three broadly identifiable categories. First are the countries, and regions within countries, in which institutions, policies, and geography are all reasonably favorable. The coastal regions of east Asia (coastal China and essentially all of Korea, Taiwan Province of China, Hong Kong SAR, Singapore, Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia) have this beneficent combination and, as a result, have all become closely integrated with global production systems and benefited from large inflows of foreign capital. Second are the regions that are relatively well endowed geographically but, for historical reasons, have had poor governance and institutions. These include the central European states, whose proximity to Western Europe brought them little benefit during the socialist regime. For such countries, institutional reforms are paramount. And, finally, there are impoverished regions with an unfavorable geography, such as most of sub-Saharan Africa, central Asia, large parts of the Andean region, and the highlands of Central America, where globalization has not succeeded in raising living standards and may, indeed, have accelerated the brain drain and capital outflows from the region. The countries that have experienced the severest economic failures in the recent past have all been characterized by initial low levels of income and small populations (and hence small internal markets) that
Finance & Development June 2003 39

Bauxite spills from chutes into freight wagons in Ghana. Despite being well endowed with natural resources, Ghana remains heavily dependent on international financial and technical assistance. live far from coasts and are burdened by disease, especially AIDS, tuberculosis, and malaria. These populations have essentially been trapped in poverty because of their inability to meet the market test for attracting private capital inflows. tion; migration of the population from the interior to the coast; or sufficient foreign assistance to build the infrastructure needed to link the region profitably with world markets. Migration would be the purest free market approach, yet the international system denies that option on a systematic basis; migration is systemically feasible only within countries. When populations do migrate from the hinterlands, the host country often experiences a political upheaval. The large migration from Burkina Faso to Côte d’Ivoire was one trigger of recent ethnic riots and civil violence. A fourth and longer-term strategy that merits consideration is regional integration: a breaking down of artificial political barriers that limit the size of markets and condemn isolated countries to relative poverty. In this regard, the recent initiative to strengthen subregional and regional cooperation in Africa should certainly be supported. Yet, given political realities, this process will be too slow, by itself, to overcome the crisis of the poorest inland regions. A good test of successful development strategy in these geographically disadvantaged regions is whether development efforts succeed in attracting new capital inflows. The structural adjustment era in sub-Saharan Africa, for example, was very disappointing in this dimension. Although the region focused on economic reforms for nearly two decades, it attracted very little foreign (or even domestic) investment, and what it did attract largely benefited the primary commodity sectors. Indeed, these economies remained almost completely dependent on a few primary commodity exports. The reform efforts did not solve the underlying fundamental

When institutions and geography matter It is a common mistake to believe—and a weak argument to make—that geography equals determinism. Even if good health is important to development, not all malarial regions are condemned to poverty. Rather, special investments are needed to fight malaria. Landlocked regions may be burdened by high transport costs but are not necessarily condemned to poverty. Rather, special investments in roads, communications, rail, and other transport and communications facilities are even more important in those regions than elsewhere. Such regions may also require special help from the outside world to initiate self-sustaining growth. A poor coastal region near a natural harbor may be able to initiate long-term growth precisely because few financial resources are needed to build roads and port facilities to get started. An equally poor landlocked region, however, may be stuck in poverty in the absence of outside help. A major project to construct roads and a port would most likely exceed local financing possibilities and may well have a rate of return far below the world market cost of capital. The market may be right: it is unlikely to pay a market return to develop the hinterland without some kind of subsidy from the rest of the world. Nor will institutional reforms alone get the goods to market. In the short term, only three alternatives may exist for an isolated region: continued impoverishment of its popula40 Finance & Development June 2003

problems of disease, geographical isolation, and poor infrastructure. The countries, unattractive to potential investors, could not break free from the poverty trap, and market-based infrastructure projects could not make up the difference.

Helping the poorest regions Development thinking and policy must return to the basics: both institutions and resource endowments are critical, not just one or the other. That point was clear enough to Adam Smith but has been forgotten somewhere along the way. A crucial corollary is that poverty traps are real: countries can be too poor to find their own way out of poverty. That is, some locales are not favorable enough to attract investors under current technological conditions and need international help in even greater amounts than have been made available to them in recent decades. An appropriate starting point for the international community would be to set actual developmental goals for such regions rather than “make do” with whatever economic results emerge. The best standards, by far, would be the Millennium Development Goals, derived from the international commitments to poverty alleviation adopted by all countries of the world at the UN Millennium Assembly of September 2000. The goals call for halving the 1990 rates of poverty and hunger by the year 2015 and reducing child mortality rates by two-thirds. Dozens of the poorest countries—those trapped in poverty—are too far off track to achieve these goals. Fortunately, at last year’s UN Financing for Development Conference held in Monterrey, Mexico, and at the World Summit on Sustainable Development held in Johannesburg, South Africa, the industrial world reiterated its commitment to help those countries by increasing debt

relief and official development assistance, including concrete steps toward the international target of 0.7 percent of donor GNP. The extra $125 billion a year that would become available if official development assistance were raised from the current 0.2 percent of GNP to 0.7 percent of GNP should easily be enough to enable all well-governed poor countries to achieve the Millennium Development Goals. Like official development assistance, debt-relief mechanisms have been wholly inadequate to date. Armed with these goals and assurances of increased donor assistance, the international community, both donors and recipients, should be able to identify, for each country and in much greater detail than in the recent past, those obstacles— whether institutional, geographical, or other (including barriers to trade in the rich countries)—that are truly impeding economic development. For each of the Millennium Development Goals, detailed interventions—including their costs, organization, delivery mechanisms, and monitoring— can be assessed and agreed upon by stakeholders and donors. By freeing our thinking from one-factor explanations and understanding that poverty may have as much to do with malaria as with the exchange rate, we will become much more creative and expansive in our approach to the poorest countries. And, with this broader view, the international institutions can also be much more successful than past generations in helping to free these countries from their economic suffering.

Jeffrey D. Sachs is Director of the Earth Institute at Columbia University and is a special adviser to the UN secretary-general on the UN Millennium Development Goals.

References: Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, 2001, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91 (December), pp. 1369–1401. Bloom, David E., and Jeffrey D. Sachs, 1998, “Geography, Demography, and Economic Growth in Africa,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2, Brookings Institution, pp. 207–95. Démurger, Sylvie, and others, 2002, “Geography, Economic Policy, and Regional Development in China,” Asian Economic Papers, Vol. 1 (Winter), pp. 146–97. Easterly, William, and Ross Levine, 2002, “Tropics, Germs and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development,” NBER Working Paper 9106 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Gallup, John Luke, and Jeffrey D. Sachs with Andrew D. Mellinger, 1998, “Geography and Economic Development,” paper presented at the Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C., April. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi, 2002, “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development,” NBER Working Paper 9305 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Sachs, Jeffrey D., 2002a , “A New Global Effort to Control Malaria,” Science, Vol. 298 (October), pp. 122–24. ———, 2002b, “Resolving the Debt Crisis of Low-Income Countries,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution, pp. 257–86. ———, 2003, “Institutions Don’t Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income,” NBER Working Paper 9490 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). ——— and Pia Malaney, 2002, “The Economic and Social Burden of Malaria,” Nature Insight, Vol. 415 (February), pp. 680–85. United Nations Development Program, 2003, Human Development Report (New York), forthcoming.

Finance & Development June 2003

41

References: Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, 2001, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91 (December), pp. 1369–1401. Bloom, David E., and Jeffrey D. Sachs, 1998, “Geography, Demography, and Economic Growth in Africa,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2, Brookings Institution, pp. 207–95. Démurger, Sylvie, and others, 2002, “Geography, Economic Policy, and Regional Development in China,” Asian Economic Papers, Vol. 1 (Winter), pp. 146–97. Easterly, William, and Ross Levine, 2002, “Tropics, Germs and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development,” NBER Working Paper 9106 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Gallup, John Luke, and Jeffrey D. Sachs with Andrew D. Mellinger, 1998, “Geography and Economic Development,” paper presented at the Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C., April. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi, 2002, “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development,” NBER Working Paper 9305 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). Sachs, Jeffrey D., 2002a , “A New Global Effort to Control Malaria,” Science, Vol. 298 (October), pp. 122–24. ———, 2002b, “Resolving the Debt Crisis of Low-Income Countries,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution, pp. 257–86. ———, 2003, “Institutions Don’t Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income,” NBER Working Paper 9490 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research). ——— and Pia Malaney, 2002, “The Economic and Social Burden of Malaria,” Nature Insight, Vol. 415 (February), pp. 680–85. United Nations Development Program, 2003, Human Development Report (New York), forthcoming. Finance & Development June 2003 41

You May Also Find These Documents Helpful

  • Better Essays

    There is no secret that some countries are more prosperous and developed than others. Why are some countries poor and there is nothing we can do about it? Is the answer culture, weather, economics, geography, bad policies, or simple bad luck? This is probably the most important question facing the world today, especially for the over three billion people that live in less than $2.50 a day. Economists, political philosophers and political figures have been trying to come up with a solution to fix this problem for hundred of years. The book “Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty” by economists Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson state that while economic institutions are vital to prosperity, it is man-made political institutions that determine if a country is prosperous or poor.1 This is concluded because any economic institution is implemented by the political class that work within the framework of a pre set legal tradition and political system, generally contained in a country’s Constitution and other society foundation documents such as the Declaration of Independence. Therefore, the framework that leads to prosperity (or lack of it) is as follows; the people enact a Constitution based on a core set of founding principles, that sets forth a society’s goals, the political class then implements economic institutions that in turn determine how prosperous a country is. But why do similar theoretical political institutions and legal traditions work so differently in practice? The answer lies in the philosophical foundations of societies.…

    • 2997 Words
    • 12 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Good Essays

    The institutions inculcate that one’s worth can only be measured using material success. The economically deprived are perceived to have a lower value in the society and are a threat to the development, because the resources spent on them do not measure to their contribution towards the resource generation. Such ideologies have resulted into the increasing disparity between the rich and the economically deprived. The ideologies have also encouraged the existence of a government that continues to enrich the wealthy while oppressing the population with the greatest needs.…

    • 999 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    In the most globalized era to date, the world faces many policy debates and questions. Many are fearful of globalization and are worried about the negative consequences it can produce. Brawley addresses these concerns in Chapter 3, “What People Fear-or Anticipate-about Globalization”. One issue people have about globalization is its ability to widen the gap of inequality between the rich and the poor, both domestically and across borders. Krugman uses the United States of America as a basis for the study of inequality in his chapter “Inequality and Redistribution.” On a global scale, Easterly explores foreign aid as a remedy for inequality in developing states in his chapter “The Legend of the Big Push.”…

    • 1551 Words
    • 7 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    Ipa Cheat Sheet

    • 2135 Words
    • 9 Pages

    AIPA 2: UNDERSTANDING ACTORS, INTERESTS & POWER Institutions  Basic level – states exist to provide (1) defence and (2) social order  this requires the presence of a functioning economy.  State not only produces, consumes and redistributes; it’s also the main source and enforcer of “rules of games”.  “Rules of games” are institutions  institutional quality is related to economic performance.  Evidence: No country has gotten rich with bad institutions. Politics  Politics is the process of creating new institutions. Existing institutions create a constraint on this process.  Political processes can be analysed in terms of Actors involved in the processes, their interests and their relative power (AIP).  Actors: Political, Societal(land, labour, capital, business associations, unions, students, military), International (hegemon, institutions)  Interests: Assume, Deduce or Judge by stated intention and observed behaviour.  Power: voter base, past performance, military control, resource control, shared nationalism/ethnicity, moral authority, int’l support  Usually, the actor with greatest relative power wins. IPA 3: STATE STRUCTURES 1: ENDS, DECISION-MAKING & IMPLEMENTATION Ends = the ultimate end of economic policy, not necessarily what is said.  Self-enrichment - “rentier state” e.g. Zaire, Congo. Anything possible for highest bidder.  Economic Development - “developmental state” e.g. Japan, S. Korea. Risk-sharing and high intervention with bias to domestic firms.  Equal outcomes - “welfare state” e.g. Scandinavia, Netherlands. Minor state intervention, heavily regulated, little adjustments & intervention.  Equal opportunity - “regulatory state” e.g. US, Hong Kong. Minor state intervention, light regulations & adjustments Decision-Making…

    • 2135 Words
    • 9 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    Half of these people, living in Sub-Saharan Africa, survive on below $2.00 a day. On the other hand, the income inequality that arrived with the advent of the industrial revolution has been steadily increasing in most developing and developed nations (UN, 2016). While it is tempting to think that the two completely correlate with each other, Dr. Sachs argues otherwise. Poverty in places like Sub-Saharan Africa is, he says, not because of rising income inequality or globalization for that matter, but because globalization has largely bypassed the region hardly influencing it or stimulating growth (Scientific American, 2016). It is at this stage that investments towards development enter the…

    • 845 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    Two competing explanations for why poor countries remain poor are (1) the poor quality of their institutions and…

    • 3403 Words
    • 14 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    References: Fields, G. (2000). Distribution and development: a new look at the developing world. Cambridge & London: MIT Press.…

    • 1092 Words
    • 5 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Best Essays

    Good governance is an essential pre-condition for pro-poor growth as it establishes the enabling regulatory and legal framework essential for the sound functioning of land, labor, capital and other factor markets.” At times, personal bad decisions made by people aren 't the reason they are stuck in poverty but lack of government leadership could be the reason. Failure to differentiate between the bad decisions people make and the bad environments within which poor people often make decisions has had dealing with the consequences for our understanding of inequality. No politician or elected official will ever accept responsibility for addressing poverty. Unfortunately, the government support received or availability of programs that are intended to help out those in need does not nearly meet the demand for them. Many get eliminated altogether when budgets get stressed, even if there is much that governments can directly do to reduce poverty. What is missing is the political demand for anti-poverty action.…

    • 2831 Words
    • 12 Pages
    Best Essays
  • Better Essays

    Lee, Cheol-Sung, François Nielsen, and Arthur S. Alderson. "Income Inequality, Global Economy and the State." Social Forces 86.1 (2007): 77-111.JSTOR. Web. 7 Feb 2013.…

    • 1854 Words
    • 8 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Good Essays

    Latin America Essay

    • 806 Words
    • 4 Pages

    The inclusive/Liberal institutions had the purpose of stimulating comparative international advantages, as well as invest in entrepreneurial incentives to the citizens resulting in technological innovations. The extractive/Mercantilist institutions, on the other hand, were “centrally concern with maximizing wealth generation in the short run” (2010: 21) as Mahoney explains, only for benefits to the ruling elites, providing no incentive to the citizens to participate in any economic activity or encourage technological innovations. Furthermore, Mahoney presents another variable that may affect development today and it is the “level of colonialism” in which the colonies – with not regards of its type of institutions – are immerged in the colonized territories. There are two different outcomes that are based on both, the type of colonial institutions and the level of colonialism: Higher or lower level of development.…

    • 806 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    This paper will analyze the arguments on development and underdevelopment from the point of view of David Landes and Andre Gunder Frank. At the very beginning of Frank’s essay, he clarifies three characteristics of countries, developed, underdeveloped and undeveloped. Meaning of developed country is obvious but Frank states that there are misconceptions about the other two terms. Undeveloped basically refers to countries that is not yet start developing or did not manage to develop whereas underdeveloped means not completely developed but still developing. Some of underdeveloped countries are dealing with the issue of disparities in income and cultural differences among the society. This situation leads to existence of social classes and this is called ‘dual society’. Main reason of this problem is while the capitalists are growing economically, the other part remains isolated thus they are less developed.…

    • 288 Words
    • 2 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Good Essays

    Hill, Lewis E. "The Institutional Economics of Poverty: An Inquiry into the Causes and Effects of Poverty." Journal of Economic Issues (1998): 279-285.…

    • 501 Words
    • 3 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    In the “The Ideology of Development”(Easterly W.,July-August 2007) the author argues that the ideology that “governs” our century , the Developmentlism , is one more ideology that fails to solve all the world’s problems. The author claims that the main purpose of Developmentalism is to find a correct answer to all of society’s ills other ideologies such as communism , fascism and socialism failed to do so . At the International Monetary Fund (IMF) some experts have made up Development’s intelligentsia . It was thought that Developmentalism found the right answer for the poor world , which was “free markets” but it was proved that in some countries even though there were made attempts to implement it , it wasn’t successful and people turned to the old ideologies .…

    • 681 Words
    • 3 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    the study of economic development is one of the newest, most exciting and most challenging branches of the broader disciplines of economics and political economy. Although development economics often draws relevant principles and…

    • 1915 Words
    • 8 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Good Essays

    In the theoretical framework, I argued that some structural factors influence economic development but depending on the political regime. Some of these factors can play strong and key role in determining ruler’s policy choices in improving and advancing national wealth and creating economic development in one regime but becomes less relevant in the other. This section have carefully explored and explained these structural factors.…

    • 811 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays