Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect
Telecommunications Policy
URL: www.elsevier.com/locate/telpol
Regulation and competition in the European mobile communications industry: An examination of the implementation of mobile number portability
Bele´n Usero Sa´nchez n, Grigorios Asimakopoulos 1
Business Management Division, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, C/Madrid, 126 (28903) Getafe, Madrid, Spain
a r t i c l e i n f o
abstract
Available online 21 December 2011
Over the past two decades, the mobile communications industry has seen a considerable drop in the consumer switching charges made by service providers in order to promote effective competition and ensure a level playing field for new market entrants.
Mobile Number Portability (MNP) is an important regulatory measure taken to reduce switching costs, and it is believed to play an important role in fostering competition in the mobile market. MNP implementation has varied significantly across European
Union countries, particularly with respect to porting time and customer fees, both of which are important factors when deciding whether to switch to another provider. The research examines the effects of MNP implementation on competition in the European mobile communications industry. The study findings indicate that subscriber churn rates are negatively affected by both the level of charges levied on subscribers wishing to maintain their current number (porting) when switching mobile providers and the length of time required to switch. The implications of the effectiveness of MNP regulation for competition in the mobile communications industry are discussed.
& 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Mobile number portability (MNP)
Regulation
Competition
Switching costs
Mobile communications industry
1. Introduction
The mobile communications industry is a source of substantial growth for the European economy. In the European
Union, total mobile
References: Ahn, J. H., Han, S. P., & Lee, Y. S. (2006). Customer churn analysis: Churn determinants and mediation effects of partial defection in the Korean mobile telecommunications service industry Aoki, R., & Small, J. (1999). The economics of number portability: Switching costs and two-part tariffs. Working paper. New Zealand: University of Auckland. Armstrong, M., & Wright, J. (2007). Two-sided markets, competitive bottlenecks and exclusive contracts. Economic Theory, 32(2), 353–380. Beggs, A., & Klemperer, P. (1992). Multiperiod competition with switching costs. Econometrica, 60(3), 651–666. BEREC (2010). Report on best practices to facilitate switching. Retrieved from /http://www.erg.eu.int/doc/consult/bor_10_34_switching.pdfS. Bijwaard, G., Janssen, M., & Massland, E. (2008). Early mover advantages: An empirical analysis of European mobile phone markets. Telecommunications Policy, 32(3-4), 246–261. Bouckaert, J. M. C., Degryse, H. A., & Provoost, T. (2010). Enhancing market power by reducing switching costs. Economics Letters, 109(2), 131–133. Buehler, S., & Haucap, J. (2004). Mobile number portability. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 4(3), 223–238. Chaterjee, S., & Price, B. (1991). Regression analysis by example. NewYork: John Wiley and Sons. Corrocher, N., & Zirulia, L. (2009). Me and you and everyone we know: An empirical analysis of local network effects in mobile communications. Dewenter, R., & Haucap, J. (2005). The effects of regulating mobile termination rates for asymmetric networks. European Journal of Law and Economics, 20(2), 185–197. Dic, J., k, A. S., & Basu, K. (1994). Customer loyalty: Toward an integrated conceptual framework. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 22(2), 99–113. Doganogl, K., u, T., & Grzybowski, L. (2007). Estimating network effects in mobile telephony in Germany. Information Economics and Policy, 19(1), 65–79. ECC (2005). Implementation of mobile number portability in CEPT countries (ECC report 31). In Proceedings of European conference of postal and telecommunications administrations ECC (2010). Number portability efficiency: Impact and analysis of certain aspects in article 30.4 of the universal service directive and general remarks on NP efficiency European Commission (2007). European electronic communications regulation and markets 2006 (12th report). SEC (2007)403. Retrieved from /http://ec. European Commission (2009). Progress report on the single European electronic communications market 2008 (14th report). SEC (2009)376. Retrieved from /http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2009:0140:FIN:EN:PDFS. European Commission (2011). Electronic communications market indicators. Retrieved from /http://ec.europa.eu/information_society/digital-agenda/ scoreboard/docs/pillar/electronic_communications.pdfS. Gabrielsen, T. S., & Vagstad, S. (2008). Why is on-net traffic cheaper than off-net traffic? Access markup as a collusive device. European Economic Review, 52(1), 99–115. Grzybowski, L. (2005). Regulation of mobile telephony across the European Union: An empirical analysis. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 28(1), 47–67. Grzybowski, L. (2008). Estimating switching costs in mobile telephony in the UK. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 8(2), 113–132. Hoernig, S. (2007). On-net and off-net pricing on asymmetric telecommunications networks. Information Economics and Policy, 19(2), 171–188. Kim, H. S., & Kwon, N. (2003). The advantage of network size in acquiring new subscribers: A conditional logit analysis of the Korean mobile telephony market Kim, H. S., & Yoon, C. H. (2004). Determinants of subscriber churn and customer loyalty in the Korean mobile telephony market. Telecommunications Policy, 28(9–10), 751–765. Klemperer, P. (1995). Competition when consumers have switching costs: An overview with applications to industrial organization macroeconomics, and international trade Koski, H., & Kretschmer, T. (2004). Survey on competing in network industries: Firm strategies, market outcomes, and policy implications. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 4(1), 5–31. Laffont, J. J., Rey, P., & Tirole, J. (1998). Network competition: II. Price discrimination. RAND Journal of Economics, 29(1), 38–56. Lambeek, A. (2009). Mobile technology: Driving change and opportunity in developing countries. International trade forum (Vol. 3). Retrieved from /http://www.tradeforum.org/Mobile-technology-Driving-change-and-opportunity-in-developing-countries/S. Lee, J., Kim, Y., Lee, J. D., & Park, Y. (2006). Estimating the extent of potential competition in the Korean mobile telecommunications market: Switching costs and number portability Lyons, S. (2010). Measuring the effects of mobile number portability on service prices. Journal of Telecommunications Management, 2(4), 357–368. Maicas, J. P., Polo, Y., & Sese, F. (2009). Reducing the level of switching costs in mobile communications: The case of mobile number portability. McCloughan, P., & Lyons, S. (2006). Accounting for ARPU: New evidence from international panel data. Telecommunications Policy, 30(10–11), 521–532. Nester, J., Wasserman, W., & Kutner, H. (1985). Applied linear statistical models. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. Padilla, A. J. (1995). Revisiting dynamic duopoly with consumer switching costs. Journal of Economic Theory, 67(2), 520–530. Shi, M., Chiang, J., & Rhee, B. D. (2006). Price competition with reduced consumer switching costs: The case of ‘‘wireless number portability’’ in the cellular phone industry Shin, D. H., & Kim, W. Y. (2007). Mobile number portability on customer switching behavior: In the case of the Korean mobile market. Info, 9(4), 38–54. Shy, O. (2002). A quick-and-easy method for estimating switching costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20(1), 71–87. Srinuan, P. (2010). Evaluating the swedish mobile communications market: Switching costs and network effects. Licenciate dissertation. Chalmers University of Technology Sutherland, E. (2007). Mobile number portability. Info, 9(4), 10–24. Valletti, V. V., & Cave, M. (1998). Competition in UK mobile communications. Telecommunications Policy, 22(2), 109–131. Viard, B. (2007). Do switching costs make markets more or less competitive?: The case of 800-number portability. Rand Journal of Economics, 38(1), 146–163. Wooldridge, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.