*Prof. D.O Ajakaiye and Dr. V. A. Adeyeye are of the Nigerian Institute for Social and Economic Research (NISER), Ibadan.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
The second shift was to broaden the concept of income – poverty, to a wider set of ‘basic needs’, including those provided socially. Thus, following ILO’s pioneering work in the mid – 1970s, poverty came to be defined not just as lack of income, but also as lack of access to health, education and other services. Conceptualization of poverty gathered fresh momentum in the 1980s. The principal innovations were five: First was the incorporation of non – monetary aspects, particularly as a result of Robert Chamber’s work on powerlessness and isolation. This helped to inspire greater attention to participation. Second was a new interest in
vulnerability and security, associated with better understanding of seasonality and of the impact of shocks. This pointed to the importance of assets as buffers, and also to social relations (the moral economy, social capital). It led to new work on coping strategies. Third was the broadening of the concept of poverty to a wider construct, livelihood. Fourth and perhaps more innovative was the theoretical work by Amartya Sen, which introduced the notion of food entitlement, or access. He emphasized that income was only valuable in so far as it increased the ‘capabilites’ of individuals and thereby permitted ‘ functioning’s’ in society. Finally, the 1980s was characterized by a rapid increase in the study of gender. The debate moved from a focus on women alone (women in development (WID), to wider gender relations (gender and development (GAD). Policies to empower women and redress gender poverty gap were then given enhanced attention. The 1990s saw further development of the poverty concept. The idea of well – being came to act as a metaphor for absence of poverty, with concomitant emphasis on how poor people themselves view their situation: “The voice of the poor” At the same time, inspired by Sen, UNDP developed the idea of human development: ‘ the denial of opportunities and choice…….. to lead a long, healthy, creative life and to enjoy a decent standard of living, freedom, dignity, self – esteem and the respect of others……..’
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Major merit of tracing the evolution of poverty conceptualization measurement and determinants is that it provides insight into the fault lines in poverty analysis and conceptual debate. There are nine of such fault lines. First are: individual or household measures. Early measurement of poverty (e.g. by Rowntree) was at the household level, and much still is. Other analysis disaggregates to the individual level, so as to capture intra – household factors and different types and causes of deprivation affecting men, women, children, old people, etc. Second is poverty conceptualized from view point of private consumption only or private consumption plus publicly provided goods? In this view poverty can be defined in terms of private income or consumption (usually consumption rather than income, in order to allow for consumption smoothing over time, e.g by managing savings). Third is monetary or monetary plus non – monetary components of poverty. On the basis of this thought money – metric measures of poverty are often used, because they are either regarded as sufficient on their own or seen as an adequate proxy for poverty. However, there is a clear fault line between definitions of poverty which are restricted to income (or consumption) and those which incorporate such factors as autonomy, self – esteem or participation. In Maslow’s hierarchy of needs, these were seen as higher needs, which would become more important as basic needs for food, shelter, housing and safety were met. The fourth is that which analyzed poverty as a Snapshot or timeline. On the basis of this many surveys and poverty assessments report the incidence of poverty at a point in time. However, there is a long history of thinking about poverty in terms of life cycle experience (e.g. Chayanov’s pioneering work in the 1920s on the peasant household), seasonal stress, and shocks (illness, drought, war). In both North and South, there has been increasing attention to understanding movement in and out of poverty, what Jenkins calls’ bottom – end churning’. Fifth is poverty perception as actual or potential. By this some analysts conclude that the poor are those who are highly sensitive to shocks, or not resilient. In this group area the vulnerable e.g Small – scale pastoralists exposed to the risk of drought, the elderly etc. Sixth has to do with the stock or flow measures of poverty. In this regard the definition of poverty as income focuses
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
on the flow of material goods and services. An alternative is to examine the stock of resources a household controls. This may be measured in terms of physical or monetary assets (Land, Jewellery, Cash), or in terms of social capital (social contacts, networks, reciprocal relationships, community membership). Seventh is input or output measures of poverty. Sen has reminded us that poverty measured as a shortfall in income
essentially captures an input to an individual’s capability and functioning rather than a direct measure of well-being. Thus writing about poverty has often assumed, wrongly, an automatic link between income and participation, or functioning, in the life of a community. Eighth consideration is absolute or relative poverty. The World Bank currently uses a figure of $US 1 per day (in 1985 purchasing power dollars) for absolute poverty. The alternative has been to define poverty as relative deprivation, for example as half mean income, or as exclusion from participation in society. Thus the European Union has decided that ‘the poor shall be taken to mean persons, families and groups of persons whose resources (material, cultural, social) are so limited as to exclude them from the minimum acceptable way of life. Finally there is the objective or subjective perceptions of poverty. In this regard, the use of participation methods has greatly
encouraged an epistemology of poverty which relies on local understanding and perceptions. For example, exposure to domestic violence may be seen as important in one community, dependency on traditional structures in another, thanks to “The voice of the poor”. Given all these, the appropriate question to ask is whether there is a right answer to the concept of poverty. The answer is certainly ‘no’, but current thinking does allow some simplification. First, poverty needs to be understood first and foremost as a
problem at the individual rather than the household level. Second is the use of income or food measure of poverty. Third, is the settled consens us that people move in and out poverty, and that seasonal, cyclical or stochastic shocks are important in poverty conceptualization and measurement. Beyond these areas of agreement, there are different views on whether assets, including social claims, should be counted in a poverty matrix, on the importance of vulnerability, and on the relative prioritization of monetary and non
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
– monetary variables. What is becoming clear in contemporary literature on poverty is that the most radical proponents of a participatory approach would deny the validity of standardized, so – called objective measures of poverty, whether based on income or wealth. Chambers, for example, has argued that these approaches are reductionist. On the basis of the above it becomes clear that conceptualizing poverty itself is problematic. Since this exercise is necessary for proper identification of the poor and their effective targeting in a more pragmatic approach to poverty alleviation, the next section has attempted to present in lucid form the concept of poverty. II. CONCEPT OF POVERTY A concise and universally accepted definition of poverty is elusive largely because it affects many aspects of the human conditions, including physical, moral and psychological. Different criteria have, therefore, been used to conceptualize poverty. Most analyses follow the conventional view of poverty as a result of insufficient income for securing basic goods and services. Others view poverty, in part, as a function of education, health, life expectancy, child mortality etc. Blackwood and Lynch (1994), identify the poor, using the criteria of the levels of consumption and expenditure. Further, Sen (1983), relates poverty to entitlements which are taken to be the various bundles of goods and services over which one has command, taking into cognisance the means by which such goods are acquired (for example, Money and Coupons etc) and the availability of the needed goods. Yet, other experts see poverty in very broad terms, such as being unable to meet “basic needs” – (physical; (food, health care, education, shelter etc. and non – physical; participation, identity, etc) requirements for a meaningful life (World Bank, 1996). Poverty may arise from changes in average income or changes in the distribution of income. Let us for instance, assume a relationship between the poverty line (L) below which an individual is poor and the average incomes of the population (Y). The poverty
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
index will decrease (increase) as L (Y) increases (decreases). Since higher average incomes are above the poverty line, other things being equal there will be less poverty. Among the “other things” that are equal is the distribution of income. Compare for instance, two countries with identical mean incomes (and poverty line), but with one having a wider area of distribution of incomes (that is one with greater income
inequality); poverty will generally be greater in the country with higher inequality, since there will be relatively more people with incomes lower than the poverty line (L). Thus, the distribution of income has an important influence on poverty. Social science literature is replete with attempts by economists and social scientists to conceptualize the phenomenon of poverty. Broadly, poverty can be
conceptualized in four ways; these are lack of access to basic needs/goods; a result of lack of or impaired access to productive resources; outcome of inefficient use of common resources; and result of “exclusive mechanisms”. Poverty as lack of access to basic needs/goods is essentially economic or consumption oriented. It explains poverty in material terms and specifically employs consumption-based c ategories to explain the extent and depth of poverty, and establish who is and who is not poor. Thus, the poor are conceived as those individuals or households in a particular society, incapable of purchasing a specified basket of basic goods and services. Basic goods are nutrition, shelter/housing, water, healthcare, access to productive resources including education, working skills and tools and political and civil rights to participate in decisions concerning socio-economic conditions (Streeten and Burki,1978). The first three are the basic needs/goods necessary for survival. Impaired access to productive resources
(agricultural land, physical capital and financial assets) leads to absolute low income, unemployment, undernourishment etc. Inadequate endowment of human capital is also a major cause of poverty. Generally, impaired access to resources shifts the focus on poverty and it curtails the capability of individual to convert available productive resources to a higher quality of life (Sen, 1977) and (Adeyeye, 1987).
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Poverty can also be the outcome of inefficient use of common resources. This may result from weak policy environment, inadequate infrastructure, weak access to technology, credit etc. Also, it can be due to certain groups using certain mechanisms in the system to exclude “problem groups” from participating in economic development, including the democratic process. In Sub-Sahara Africa (SSA) , the agricultural sector was exploited through direct and indirect taxation throughout the colonial and post-colonial decades leading to poor growth performance of the sector, heightened rural- urban migration and employment crisis. In urban SSA, Silver (1994) suggests three paradigms of exclusion: the individual’s specialization that cannot be accommodated in the factor market (specialization paradigms); the various interest groups that establish control over the
input of available resources, for example, on goods and labour markets and simultaneously foster solidarity within the respective interest groups (monopoly paradigms); and the individual which has a troubled relationship with the community (solidarity paradigm). Poverty can be structural (chronic) or transient. The former is defined as
persistent or permanent socio-economic deprivations and is linked to a host of factors such as limited productive resources, lack of skills for gainful employment, endemic socio-political and cultural factors and gender. The latter, on the other hand, is defined as transitory/temporary and is linked to natural and man- made disasters. Transient poverty is more reversible but can become structural if it persists. It is generally agreed that in conceptualizing poverty, low income or low consumption is its symptom. This has been used for the construction of poverty lines. Various theories have been advanced in order to put in proper perspective the mechanics of poverty. The orthodox Western views of poverty, reflected in the “Vicious circle” hypothesis stating that a poor person is poor because he is poor, and may remain poor, unless the person’s income level increases significantly enough to pull the person in question out of the poverty trap. To the classical school of thought, such improvement can only be real and sustained, if and only if, the population growth is checked and the “limits of growth” are eliminated. Further, the early classical theorists in the attempt to
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
illuminate on the concept of poverty based their analytical framework on the laws of diminishing returns which was believed to be universal in content although this was later upgraded at the time of Alfred Marshall and his contemporaries when the law of increasing retur ns in industry was more clearly articulated. Understanding the nature of poverty perhaps received a boost following Marxian theoretical formulation largely based on the principle of exploitation of labour. Marxian theoretical formulations presents the economy as ultimately polarized into a few rich capitalists and the masses made up of the poor miserable workers. Technological
progress, it was argued, would be labour saving, resulting in displacement of workers to join the reserved army of the unemployed, whose presence depresses the wage level. Joseph Bocke developed a model of dualistic economies which was later popularized by Arthur Lewis. In accordance with this model, the national economy was divided with two parallel institutional production sectors, namely, the traditional sector and the modern sector. The latter is dominated by foreign trade, technology investment and foreign management and is characterized by the beneficial values of discipline, hard work and productive creativity. On the other hand, in the traditional sector, the static low- level equilibrium conditions advanced by the vicious circle of poverty theory are said to hold. According to this school of thought, the subsistence life style and a cultural value that are antitheses to economic growth and modernization dominate. Local
ineptitude and the people’s apparent lack of response to normal monetary incentives to hard work, therefore provide explanation for poverty. This intuitively implies that the poor person is the cause of his/her poverty. Understanding the nature of poverty became upgraded with the modern theoretical approach that considers the income dimension as the core of most povertyrelated problems. Poverty may arise from changes in average income, or changes in the distributed income. Equitably distributed income increases the chance of the poor to have access to basic services (food consumption, housing etc), Indeed, it is now generally agreed that although there is close positive relationship between per capita income (PCI) and the measures of well-being, it is not so much the level of PCI which determines
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
capabilities but how it is distributed. The argument for growth as a precondition for poverty reduction is because it increases, mean incomes and the narrowing of income distribution. Again, a major lesson that can be drawn from the conceptualization of poverty above is that any attempt to design pragmatic approach to poverty alleviation has to adopt mixture of strategies since poverty is multifaceted in scope and dimension. But how do we measure poverty without lossing sight of its various dimensions?
III. MEASUREMENT OF POVERTY Poverty measurement is undertaken to: • • • • • • • • • * Determine a yardstick for measuring standard of living. Choose a cut-off poverty line, which separates the poor from the non-poor (indication of how many people are poor). Take account of the distribution of standard of living among the poor. Comparison of poverty overt time, among individuals, group or nations. Guide policy on poverty alleviation. There are certain desirable properties of the measure of poverty. They are: Monotonicity axiom (i.e measure of poverty should increase when the income of the poor household decreases). The transfer axiom i.e poverty of household should increase when income is transferred from a poor to a less poor household. Demonstrate the distribution of living standard among the poor. The measure should be additively decomposable by population sub groups.
Measurement of poverty is complex and varied. Discussion of poverty measure has, therefore, commenced with the simple living standard measure, poverty line determination and array of measures involved in absolute and relative poverty measures. Measure of poverty that enables us show its decomposability by population, capture issue of social capital and how the poor themselves measure poverty have been highlighted.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Living standards: This is generally measured using current consumer spending or income. A measure of current consumer spending is generally preferred to income as a measure of current living standards for two reasons. First, current consumption is often taken to be a better indicator than current income because instantaneous utility depends directly on consumption, not on income per se. Second, current consumption may also be a good indicator of Long-term average well-being, as it will reveal information about incomes at other dates, in the past and future. This is because incomes (including those of the poor) often vary over time in fairly predictable ways-particularly in agrarian economies such as Nigeria. Alderman and Paxson (1992), Deaton (1992). Further, income as a measure of living standards is often questioned on the ground of incorrect rendition by the respondents. On balance, consumption expenditure is preferred to income as a measure of living standard. Poverty lines in Theory: A poverty line can be defined as the monetary cost to a given person, at a given place and time, of a reference level of welfare. People who do not attain that level of welfare are deemed poor; and those who do are not. A distinction is sometimes made between “absolute poverty line” and “relative poverty line”, whereby the former has fixed “real value” over time and space,while a relative poverty line rises with average expenditure. Arguably, for the purposes of informing anti-poverty policies, a poverty line should always be absolute in the space of welfare. Such a poverty line guarantees that the poverty comparisons made are consistent in the sense that two individuals with the same level of welfare are treated the same way. Objective Poverty Lines: Objective poverty line approaches can be interpreted as attempts to anchor the reference utility level to attain basic capabilities, of which the most commonly identified relate to the adequacy of consumption for living a healthy and active life, including participating fully in the society. Sen.(1985, 1987). Two methods of measuring objective poverty line are food energy intake and cost of basic needs. The food-energy intake method: A popular practical method of setting poverty lines involves finding the consumption expenditure or income level at which food energy
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
intake is just sufficient to meet pre-determined food energy requirements. Setting foodenergy requirements can be a difficult step. For instance, requirements vary across individuals and over time for a given individual. Food energy intake will naturally vary at a given expenditure level, y. Recognizing this fact, the method typically calculates an expected value of intake. Let k denote food-energy intake, which is a random variable. The requirement level is k which is taken to be fixed (this can be readily relaxed). As long as the expected value of food-energy intake conditional on total consumption expenditure, E (k/y), is strictly increasing in y over an interval which includes k then there will exist a poverty line z such that
E (k/z) = k
This can be termed the “food-energy- intake” (FEI) method (Ravallion, 1994a). The method has been used in numerous countries; for example see Dandekar and Rath (1971), Osmani (1982), Greer and Thorbecke (1986), and Paul (1989). Figure 1 illustrates the method. The vertical axis is food-energy intake, plotted against total income or expenditure on the horizontal axis. A line of “best fit” is
indicated; this is the expected value of caloric intake at a given value of total consumption. By simply inverting this line, one then finds the expenditure z at which a person typically attains the stipulated food-energy requirement. Figure 1: The Food-Energy Intake Method. Food-energy intake (calories per day)
2100
z
Income or expenditure.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Once food-energy requirements are set, the FEI method is computationally simple. A common practice is to calculate the mean income or expenditure of a subsample of households whose estimated calorice intake are approximately equal to the stipulated requirements. More sophisticated versions of the method use regressions of the empirical relationship between food energy intake and consumption expenditure. These can be readily used (numerically or explicitly) to calculate the FEI poverty line. The cost-of-basic-needs method: This method stipulates a consumption bundle adequate for basic consumption needs, and then estimates its cost for each of the subgroups being compared in the poverty profile; this is the approach of Rowntree in his seminal study of poverty in York in 1899, and it has been followed since in innumerable studies for both developed and developing countries. This is called the “cost-of-basicneeds” (CBN) method. One can interpret this method in two quite distinct ways. It can be interpreted as the “cost-of-utility”, By the second interpretation, the definition of “basic needs” is deemed to be a socially determined normative minimum for avoiding poverty, and the cost-of-basic- needs is then closely analogous to the idea of statutory minimum wage rate. Poverty is then measured by comparing actual expenditures to the CBN. There are food and non- food components of CBN with different computation. The Food Component: The food component of the poverty line is almost universally anchored on nutritional requirements for good health. To compute the food component of CBN a simple method is to set a bundle of goods in each region (say). One difficulty with the core basic needs method is the determination of the minimum requirement for the non- food needs. There are no agreed standards of needs for non-food items”. This is because these non-food needs are determined by environmental conditions, as well as institutional structures, technology and customary modes of life. In order compute nonfood items the monetary value can be attached to most of the non- food items. But in using this method, it is necessary that the costs of the non- food needs included should not be lower than the prevailing cost for such items, even when the minimum standards are not met.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Subjective Poverty Lines: Subjective poverty line debate has opened another issue on poverty conceptualization and measurement. Psychologists, sociologists and others have argued that the circumstances of the individual relative to others in some reference group influence perceptions of well-being at any given level of individual command over commodities. By this view, “the dividing line… between necessities and luxuries turns
out to be not objective and immutable, but socially determined and ever changing” (Scitovsky, 1978). Some have taken this view so far as to abandon any attempt to rigorously qualify “poverty”. Poverty analysis has therefore, become polarized between the “objective-quantitative” schools and “subjective-qualitative” schools, with rather little effort at cross-fertilization. “Subjective poverty lines” have been based on answers to the “minimum income question” (MIQ), such as the following (paraphrased from Kapteyn et al 1988): “What income level do you personally consider to be absolutely minimal? That is to say that with less you could not make ends meet”. One might define as poor everyone whose actual income is less than the amount they give as an answer to this question. The relationship depicted in figure 2, gives a stylized representation of the regression function on income for answers to the MIQ. The point z* in the figure is an obvious candidate for a poverty line; people with income above z* tend to feel that their income is adequate, while those below z * tend to feel that it is not. In keeping with the literature, we term z* the “subject poverty line” (SPL). SPL is subjected to “inconsistencies” in that people with the same income, or some other agreed measure of welfare will be treated differently. So, allowance must be made for heterogeneity, such that people at the same standard of living may well give different answers to the MIQ, but must be considered equally “poor” for consistency.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Figure 2: The subjective poverty line (z*) Subjective minimum Income Actual income
While the MIQ has been applied in a number of OECD countries, there have been few attempts to apply it in a developing country. There are a number of potential pitfalls. Income is not a well-defined concept in most developing countries, particularly (but not only) in rural areas. It is not at all clear whether or not one could get sensible answers to the MIQ. The qualitative idea of the “adequacy” of consumption is a more promising one in a developing country setting. Poverty Measures Absolute poverty can be measured in seven different ways. They are the
headcount ratios/incidence of poverty, the poverty gap/income shortfall, composite poverty measures, the physical quality of life index (PQLI), the augmented physical quality of life index (PAQLI), and the human development index (HDI). Head Count Ratio: Poverty can be expressed in a single index: The simplest and most common measure is the Head Count ratio (H), which is the ratio of the number of poor to total population.
CBN ECONOM IC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Where q is the number of the poor and N is total sample population. This gives the proportion of the population with income below the poverty line. The head count ratio has been criticized for its focus only on the number of the poor and being insensitive to the severity of poverty and to changes below the poverty line. That is, it treats all the poor equally, whereas not all the poor are equally poor.
The poverty gap/income shortfall: The poverty gap ratio or the income gap ratio is the difference between the poverty line and mean income of the poor, expressed as a ratio of the poverty line (World Bank, 1993). The average income shortfall. I, measure the amount of money it would take to raise the income of the average poor person up to the poverty line. That is , it provides a statement on the level of income transfer to the ‘poor’. If ya is the average income of the poor and z is the poverty line, then one measure of the depth of poverty, the income gap ratio is:
Taking the product of H and I will incorporate both the number of the poor and the depth of their poverty
Composite poverty measures The Sen index: This index is attributed to Sen (1976). It incorporates the headcount index, the income gap, and the Gini coefficient. Sen poverty index (s) is: S = H [I + (1 – I) Gp] Where ………………………. (3)
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
I y1 z qz H N Gp
= the average income shortfall as a percentage of the poverty line = income of the ith poor household = poverty line income = number of households with incomes below z = q/n; headcount ratio = total number of households = Gini coefficient among the poor = 0 = Gp > 1.
S is an increasing function of the headcount index and an increasing function of the income shortfall. Given that the Gp ranges from zero to one, S is also an increasing function of Gp: dS dH > 0 dS dI > 0 dS dGP > 0
The Sen index has a major drawback. It is more responsive to improvements in the headcount than it is to reduction in the income gap or to improvements in the distribution of income among the poor. This index indicates that the efficient way to reduce poverty is to help the least needy first and the most needy last. The physical quality of life index (PQLI): The PQLI is attributed to morris (1979). It measures how well societies satisfy certain specific ‘life-serving social characteristics’ or ‘achieved well-being’ (Doessel and Gounder, 1994). development. The PQL is based on three indicators: infant mortality, life expectancy and basic literacy. Computationally, PQL is given by: Thus its focus is on social
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
PQL
= f (IM, e, It) ………………………………….
(5)
Where IM e Lit = infant mortality = life expectancy = literacy The indices formed from these three indicators are summed up and the average give the PQLI (physical quality of life index). PQLI = (IMI +el + IitI) ……………………. (6) 3 where IMI el Lit = infant mortality index = life expectancy index = Literacy index
The human development index (HDI): The HDI is the most recent composite index devised by the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP, 1990). This index focuses on human development. It incorporates income and non-income factors. Three factors- longevity, knowledge and income are the variables of the index. Longevity is measured by life expectancy at birth (e0), knowledge is measured in terms of literacy. The third variable is per capita income. development HD is specified as: HD Where e0 lit Y = life expectancy at birth = literacy rate = per capita income = f (e0 , lit, Y) ……………………………… (7) Generally, therefore, UNDP’s human
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
These three indicators-life expectancy (X1 ), literacy (X2 ), and the logarithm of real GDP per capita (X3 ) are specified at the national level as components of the index. By looking across a range of countries, the maximum and minimum values for each indicator is established. A ‘deprivation’ index for the ith indicator and the jth country is then defined as:
Where: 0 < 1ij < 1 The UNDP (1990) defined the deprivation index for country j as a simple average of the three deprivation indices for the country and the human development index (HDI) one minus this average. Relative poverty measures: Relative poverty measures define the segment of the
population that is poor in relation to the set income of the general population. Such a poverty line is set at one-half of the mean income, or at the 40th percentile of the distribution. There are two main kinds of relative measures. Average income, this is the average income of the poorest 40 percent of the population and/or the average income of the poorest 10 or 20 percent of the population. The second is the number or population of people whose incomes are less than or equal to predetermined percentage of the mean income say 50% or less of the mean income.
Composite measure of poverty proposed by Foster, Greer and Thorbecke (FGT) (1984): Foster et al (1984) proposed a family of poverty indices, based on a single formula, capable of incorporating any degree of concern about poverty through the
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
“poverty aversion” parameter, ∝ This is the so-called P-alpha measures of poverty or the poverty gap index:
Z is the poverty line, q is the number of households/persons below the poverty line, N is total sample population, Yi is the income of the household, and ∝ is the FGT parameter, which takes the values 0, 1 and 2, depending on the degree of concern about poverty. The quantity in parentheses is the proportionate shortfall of income below the poverty line. By increasing the value of ∝ the “aversion” to poverty as measured by the index is increased. For example, where there is no aversion to poverty, ∝ = 0, the index is simply Po = 1 q = q H N N ……………………..… (11)
Which is equal to the head-count ratio. This index measures the incidence of poverty. If the degree of aversion to poverty is increased such that when ∝ = 1, the index becomes
Here the head-count ratio is multiplied by the income gap between the average poor person and the poverty line. This index measures the depth of poverty, and it is also referred to as income gap’ or ‘poverty gap’ measure. Although superior to P0 , PI still implies uniform concern about the depth of poverty, in that it weights the various income gap of the poor equally. P2 or FGT index allows for concern about the poorest of the poor through attaching greater weight to the
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
poverty of the poorest than those just below the poverty line. This is done by squaring the income gap to capture the severity of poverty:
This index satisfies the Sen-Transfer axiom which requires that when income is transferred from a poor to a poorer person, measured poverty decreases. Another advantage of the P-alpha measures is their decomposability. The overall poverty can be expressed as the sum of groups; poverty weighted by the population share of each group. Thus, P ∝ = Σkjp ∝j ………………………………. (14)
Where j= 1,2,3 … m groups, Kj is population share of each group, and P j is poverty measure for each group. The contribution of each group, Cj, to overall poverty can then be calcula ted.
The contribution to overall poverty, like in the case of inequality, well provide a guide as to where poverty is concentrated and where policy interventions should be targeted. IV. CAUSES OF POVERTY
There is no one cause or determinant of poverty. On the contrary, combination of several complex factors contribute to poverty. They include low or negative economic growth, inappropriate macroeconomic policies, deficiencies in the labour market resulting in limited job growth, low productivity and low wages in the informal sector, and a lag in human resource development. Other factors which have contributed to a decline in living standards and are structural causes or determinants of poverty include increase in
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
crime and violence, environmental degradation, retrenchment of workers, a fall in the real value of safety nets, and changes in family structures. These are examined below: Low economic growth performance: Growth of the economy is a must for poverty reduction. In developing countries such as Nigeria growth that is employment generating and with export base is desirable in order to achieve growth that is poverty reducing with equity. Although the economic performance of countries in the World has generally been highly volatile since the early 1980s, on the whole, growth rates have been low or negative, with overall declines in several countries. This is due in part to external shocks such as adverse changes in several country’s terms of trade, changes in global demand for exports and changes in global interest rates on developing countries external debt. All these are probably responsible for the increase in poverty level in various countries of the world. Extensive evidence links the importance of economic growth to poverty reduction (see World Bank 1990). For example, in Indonesia and Thailand poverty was reduced by between 30 and 40 percent during a twenty-year period in which annual growth rates were approximately 3 percent (investments in the social sectors also contributed). Accordingly, of a sample of countries, those that reduced poverty the least (for example, India and Sri Lanka) had growth rates of less than 1 percent. Growth can reduce poverty through rising employment, increased labour productivity and higher real wages it generates. Macroeconomic shocks and policy failure:- This has been a major cause of poverty in several countries of the world. As many economies in the world faced macroeconomic disequilibrium, mostly in the balance of payments due to expansive aggregate demand policies, terms-of-trade shocks, and natural disasters, it become necessary to undertake major policy reforms. In the process such economies became vulnerable to poverty. Macro-economic shocks and policy failure account for poverty largely because they constrain the poor from using their greatest asset “labour”. Also, monetary policies that adversely affect cost and access to credit by the poor, fiscal policy which results in retrenchment, lay-off and factor Substitution; exchange rate policy which raises the
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
domestic cost of production in an import dependent production system will affect the poor negatively. However, an exchange rate policy which boosts exports particularly those in which the poor are predominantly engaged (for example agriculture) will help reduce poverty. The urban poor, as a result of policy failure, are vulnerable to job losses resulting from job-cut-backs in the public sectors or from the decline of industries adversely affected by shifts in relative prices. They also lose from the removal of food subsidies and other welfare packages. Further, devaluation produce both negative and positive effects on equity and poverty incidence. On the negative side higher production costs of import, especially in import dependent economy usually result in declining capacity utilization rate in manufacturing and lay –off and retrenchment in the private sector all worsening poverty. Labour m arkets deficiencies: The poor’s most abundant resource is their labour, a verilel labour market is important to reducing poverty and income inequality. In most countries of the world the majority of poor households participate in the labour market in one way or another, and thus poverty is a problem of low wages (in the informal sector), low labour returns to rural self-employment activities, underemployment, and in some cases, protracted unemployment. These problems are affected in different ways by
deficiencies in labour market. The majority of the labour force work as paid employees in the private informal sector, followed by employees in the public sector. When there is deficiencies in labour market, the poor are affected by limited job growth and absorption capacity in the formal sector. Also, relatively high labour costs in the formal sector that lead to over expansion of a low-productivity informal sector, thus putting downward pressure on wages in the informal sector (where many of the poor work), and limited opportunities for unskilled youth to acquire job training and skills can perpetuate a cycle of poverty. Migration: Migration rates do reduce poverty especially when the majority of
individuals who migrate are skilled workers. On the other hand, individuals who
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
emigrate vacate jobs in labour markets. Thus, migration drains on skills. It reduces the pace of economic growth and thus slows the process of overall job creation and affects the long-run development potential in a country. Unemployment and underemployment: Employment is a key determinant of poverty. Gainful employment is important for individual to earn income and escape from “income” poverty. While generally in countries of the world the non poor suffer from transitional or involuntary unemployment, the poor are faced with problems of structural unemployment due to lack of skills or extremely low educational levels, medical problems, geographical isolation (which affects some of the rural poor in general and the urban poor due to marginalisation of persons living in high- crime neighborhood) and in some countries, discrimination based on race or other attributes. Further,
underemployment occurs largely in the informal sectors and results in low incomes for an important segment of the labour force, particularly in rural areas. Unemployment is due more to low economic growth than to the direct effects of imperfections in the labour market, although regulations affecting the formal sector are likely to induce more underemployment in the informal sector. In poorer, rural areas, this mainly takes the form of seasonal unemployment and in urban areas those who have given up searching for work. High unemployment particularly affects youths, women urban dwellers, and those “queuing” for good jobs in the formal sector. Human resource development: This is key for human capital development and Continued investment in human capital with
capability to escape from poverty.
improvements in efficiency is necessary to sustain reduction in poverty changes in the labour market. Investment in people can boost the living standards of households by expanding opportunities, raising productivity, attracting capital investment, and increasing earning power: In addition, providing additional educational opportunities for adolescents may prevent some youths from becoming involved with gangs, drugs and violence, given the evidence linking the perpetrators of crime with school dropouts.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
III-Health/Diseases. Good health is basic to human welfare and a fundamental objective of social and economic development. Poor health shackles human capital, reduces
returns to learning , impedes entrepreneurial activities and holds back growth and economic development. Diseases cause poverty and vice versa. In most countries of the World major diseases causing poverty are Malaria, HIV/AIDS and other
infections/diseases. In Nigeria for instance, AIDS prevalence is about 5.4% with an infected adult population of 2.6 million. This will constrain availability and participation of this segment of the population in the labour market to earn income. Debt burden: In several developing countries of the world, debt burden is assuming increasing importance as a cause of poverty. In such countries servicing of the debt has encroached on the volume of resources needed for socio-economic development. The productive sector such as agriculture, manufacturing etc are equa lly constrained leading to low productivity, low capacity utilization, under employment and low purchasing power thereby subjecting the masses of the people to abject poverty. In Nigeria, at the end of December 2000 external debt stood at US$28.5 (about 80% of GDP). Amount required to service this debt annually is enough to hamper government expenditure for the provision of social and physical infrastructure for the poor.
Governance: The persistence and pervasiveness of poverty in several countries has been linked to the lack of popular participation in governance and decision- marking as well as weak institutional base. This has led among other things to poor accountability,
transparency in resource allocation, weak programme implementation and monitoring. Ultimately, development programmes are rendered ineffective poverty reduction initiatives are therefore ineffective and resources wasted. Environmental Degradation: Environmental degradation is a cause of accentuated poverty. At the same time, poverty itself can be a cause of environmental degradation. This reverse causality stems from the fact that for poor people in poor countries such as
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Nigeria, a number of environmental resources are complementary in production and consumption to other goods and services while a number of environmental resources supplement income most especially in time of acute economic stress (Falconer and Arnold, 1989, Falconer 1990). This can be a source of cumulative causations, where poverty, high fertility rates and environmental degradation feed upon one another. In fact, an erosion of the environmental resource base can make certain categories of people destitute even when the economy on the average grows (Dasgupta, 1993) In several countries of the world inaccessibility of the poor to credit and resource inputs leave them with no choice order than to employ natural resources such as forests, woodlands and rivers in order to survive. Quite often, their continuous exploitation of these resources have led to stress/depletion and environmental degradation thereby making poor both agents and victims of unsatisfactory ecological practices. In most rural areas, developing countries fallow duration has declined to four to five years and in several instances as low as two years. Short fallow period is usually not adequate for regeneration of vegetation and the restoration of host nutrients; soil and water quality are therefore quickly depleted. Among the poor; frequent cut ting of forest trees with low replanting rate has resulted in scarcity of fuel wood. Immediate effect of this is that poor households turn to alternative fuels such as crop residues, coconut husks, rice hulls or elephant grass. The smoke from these inferior fuels according to Cece Laki (1985), is often more poisonous than that of fuel wood, while emissions from all biomass fuels are known to be dangerous sources of air pollution in the house. Also, scarcity of fuel woods forces women to make what is available burn slowly. WHO (1984), reckons that under slow burning conditions wood fuels are capable of producing pollution concentrates higher than fossil fuels and subject the households to more smoke pollutants. The incessant cutting down of trees for firewood and charcoal have hindered prospect for increased yield and hasten the prospect of the creeping desert while profligate use of the country’s resources by industries and industrial pollution from improper waste disposal has further exacerbated the plight of the poor. Other
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
consequences of over exploitation of environment due to poverty are depletion of fish in the local rivers and streams. Crime and Violence: A steady increase in crime and violence has degraded the quality of life to a varying extent in many counties of the world. Although individuals of all socioeconomic groups are affected, the urban poor are particularly vulnerable to these social problems. There are instances of shootings, gang killings, etc 38
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Crime and Violence have serious economic costs. For instance, an increasing proportion of public resources, which are already limited, is required to strengthen police enforcement, support the growing prison population, finance the demands place on the judicial system, and provide health care for persons injured by violence. Other costs include the expensive security systems and guards now required by businesses and homes, the loss in potential revenues from foreign investor and tourists who have sought other destination as a result of the threat of crime, and the migration of the urban middle class. Because of the heterogeneous nature of the poor, it is difficult to link poverty, crime and violence directly. However the adverse social consequence of crime have been closely associated with poverty e.g loss of lives at productive age and quantum loss of properties Household Determinants of poverty include: • • • • • • • • • Age and education of different household members (head), Number of income earners, Household composition and size, Assets owned by household, Access to basic social services Sex, ethnicity of head, Location variable (rural or urban), Sector of employment, Remittances to households etc.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
REFERENCES Adeyeye V.A (1987) “Rural Crisis in Nigeria: Increase in Food Deficits, Decline in Real Income and widespread Rural Poverty” paper presented at the second 1987 NISER Seminar series, Jan. 28 Adeyeye V.A (1999) “Designing Social Safety Nets for Rural Poor: Conceptual Issues Evidence and Policy choices for Developing Countries” Memio NISER, Ibadan. Adeyeye V.A (1999a) “Programming NGOs for Sustainable Assistance of the Rural Poor in Developing Countries: Options From Evidence”. Mimeo, NISER, Ibadan. Adeyeye V.A (2000) “Designing and Managing Poverty Alleviation Programme in Nigeria: The Micro-Project Option” Paper Presented at the Workshop on Poverty
Alleviation Policies and Strategies, organised by National Center for Economic Management and Administration (NCEMA), Ibadan. Adeyeye V.A (2000a) “Evolving Sustainable Strategies for Integrated poverty Alleviation Programmes in Nigeria: op. cit Ibadan Sept. 18-20 Ajakaiye D Olu and V.A Adeyeye (2001) “The Nature of Poverty in Nigeria. Technical Report, NISER, Ibadan Alderman and Paxson (1992) “Do the Poor Insure? A Synthesis of the Literature on Risk and Consumption in Developing Countries” mimeo, World Bank and Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University. 40
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Anyanwu, J.C. (1997) “ Poverty: Concepts, Measurement and Determinants” Proceeding of NES conference on Poverty Alleviation in Nigeria, Dept of Economics, University of Ibadan, Ibadan
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Atkinson, Anthony B., (1987), “On the Measurement of Poverty”, Econometrics 55: 74964. Blackwood and Lynch (1994) “The Measurement of Inequality and Poverty: A Policy Maker’s Guide to the Literature”, World development 22 (4) : 567-578 Booth, M (1891) “Labour and Life of the Peoples 1889, (1891) (2 volumes) CBN/NISER (1992). “The Impact of SAP on Nigerian Agriculture and Rural Life”. CBN/NISER Publication, NISER, Ibadan Camagarajah et al (1997) “The Evolution of Poverty and Welfare Assessment In Nigeria”, Background Document, No 1715 (Jan), World Bank, Washington D.C Cece Laki (1985) “The Rural Energy Crisis, Women’s work and Basic Needs: Perspectives and Approaches of Action” ILO Rural Employment Policy Research Programme. Technical Co-operation Report, Geneva. ILO. Coleman J. (1990) “Foundation of Social Theory” Cambridge Mass. Harvard University Press. Citron, Constance F., and Michael, Robert T., 1995, Measuring Poverty: A new Approach. Washington DC: National Academy Press. Deaton, Angus (1992) “ Understanding Consumption” Oxford University Press. Demery L. and L. Squire (1996) “Macroeconomic Adjustment and Poverty in Africa: An Emerging Picture” World Bank Research Observer. Doessel and Gounder (1994) “Theory and Measurement of Living Levels: Some
Empirical Result for the Human Development Index” Journal of International Development 6 (4) : 415-435. Dandekar, V.M., and N. Rath, 1971, Poverty in India. Pune: Indian School of Political Economy.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Dasgupta P. (1993) An Injuiry into well-being and Destitutean, Oxford Clarendan Press. Falconer and Arnold (1989) “ Household Food Security and Forestry: An Analysis of Socio- Economic Issues”. FAO, ROME. Foster, James, J. Greer, and Erik Thorbecke, 1984, “A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures”, Econometrica 52:761-66. Greer, J., and Erik – Thorbecke 1986, “A methodology for measuring food poverty applied to Kenya” Journal of Development Economics 24:59-74 Hartwick, J. (1990) “Natural Resources, National Accounting and Economic Depreciation” Journal Of Public Economics: 43 Kapteyn Arie, Peter Kooreman, and Rob Willemse, 1988, “Some Methodological Issues in the Implementation of Subjective Poverty Definitions”, The Journal of Human Resources 23:222-242. Maxwell, S (1999) “The Meaning and Measurement of Poverty” ODI Poverty Briefing, Feb. Narayam D and L Pritchett (1997) “Cents and Sociability: Household Income Social Capital in Rural Tanzania”, Policy Research Working Group Paper 1796, World Bank, Washington D.C. Nwosu A. C. and V.A Adeyeye (1989) “Are the Rural Poor Really Benefiting from SAP? Technical Report, NISER, Ibadan. Obadan, M (1997) “Analytical Framework for Poverty Reduction: Issue of Economic Growth Versurs other Strategies”: in NES op cit. Osmani, Siddiqur, 1982, Economic Inequality and Group Welfare Oxford: Oxford University Press.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Putnam R.D. (1993a) “Making Democracy Work Traditions in Modern Italy” Puiceton J.J., Princeton Press University. Paul, Satya, 1989, “A Model of Constructing the Poverty Line”, Journal of Development Economics 30:129-144. Ravallion Martin, 1992, “Does Undernutrition Respond to Incomes and Prices? Dominance Tests for Indonesia”, World Bank Economic Review 6:109-124. , 1994a, Poverty Comparisons Chur, Switzerland: Hardwood Academic Press Fundamentals of Pure and Applied Economic Volume 56. , 1994b, “Poverty Rankings Using Noisy Data on Living Standards”
Economics Letters 45:481-485.
Runciman, W.G., 1966, Relative Deprivation and Social Justice. Routledge and Kegan Paul. Rowntree, B.S., 1901, Poverty-a Study of Town Life. London: Macmillan. Scitovsky, Tibor, 1978, The Joyless Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Sen, .A. (1977) “Starvation and Exchange Entitlement: A General Approach and Its Implications to the Great Bengal Famine” Cambridge Journal of Economics 1 (1) Sen, Amartya K., 1976, “Poverty: An Ordinal Approach to Measurement”, Econometrica 46:437-446. , 1983, “Poor Relatively Speaking”, Oxford Economic Papers 35. , 1985, Commodities and Capabilities (Amsterdam: North-Holland). , 1987, The standard of Living. Cambridge University Press. Silver. H. (1994) “Social Exclusion and Social Security: Three Paradigms,” International Institute for Labour Studies. Discussion Paper Geneva.
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
Steeten, P. and S.J Burki (1978) “Basic Needs: Some Issues” World Development 6(3):411-21 Townsend, Peter, 1985, “A sociological Approach to the Measurement of Poverty: A Rejoinder to Professor Amartya San”, Oxford Economic Papers 37. World Bank, 1990, World Deve lopment Report, Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press. United Nations Development Programme (1990) “Human Development Report”, Oxford University Press, New York. World Bank (1993) “Poverty Reduction Handbook”. The World Bank, Washington D.C. 44
CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4
World Bank (1995b) “Distribution and Growth: Complements Not Compromises” Policy Research Bulletin 6(3), May-July6. World Bank (1996a) “Taking Action for Poverty Alleviation in Sub-Saharan Africa” Report of an African Task Force, May 1, World Bank, Washington D.C. World Bank (1996b). “Poverty in the Midst of Plenty. The challenge of Growth with Inclusion”. A World Bank Poverty Assessment, May 31. World Bank Washington D.C. World Health Organization (1984): “Biomass Fuel Combination and Health” Geneva, World Health Organization.
References: CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4 Atkinson, Anthony B., (1987), “On the Measurement of Poverty”, Econometrics 55: 74964 Empirical Result for the Human Development Index” Journal of International Development 6 (4) : 415-435. Dandekar, V.M., and N. Rath, 1971, Poverty in India. Pune: Indian School of Political Economy. CBN ECONOMIC & FINANCIAL REVIEW, VOL. 39 N0. 4 World Bank (1995b) “Distribution and Growth: Complements Not Compromises” Policy Research Bulletin 6(3), May-July6
You May Also Find These Documents Helpful
-
According to Henslin, race/ethnicity, gender, and education of the head of the family are the three greatest predictors of poverty (2013). Thus, believing that gender and race equality are currently being assessed in America passionately, I propose that to help more impoverished people to find their way out of poverty we must evaluate and redefine what education means. Education is the tool we armed with to carve out our life in the United States and it is the only predictor we have control of. Merriam-Webster defines skill as “a learned power of doing something competently: a developed aptitude or ability” and education as the “knowledge and development resulting from an educational process” (2017). The argument could be made that less empathize…
- 236 Words
- 1 Page
Good Essays -
Poverty is the state of being extremely poor and being inferior in quality. Nearly half of the world’s population, nearly 3 billion people, live on less than two dollars a day and the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of the poorest 48 nations is less than the wealth of the world’s three richest people combined. Poverty can be caused by many issues particularly social and economic reasons. There have been many attempts to address poverty on a global scale and these will be explored.…
- 1394 Words
- 6 Pages
Powerful Essays -
In order to debunk the negative stereotype associated with poverty, it is necessary to present relevant information to fully demonstrate the complexity of poverty. First, research will be…
- 1918 Words
- 8 Pages
Powerful Essays -
Karelis, C. (2008). The persistence of poverty. ESR Review, 10(1), 28-33 Retrieved from ABI/INFORM Global database. (1477242731)…
- 1890 Words
- 8 Pages
Good Essays -
Howard, M, Garnham, A, Fimister, G and Veit-Wilson, J (2001) Poverty; the facts. 4th edition. London: CPAG.…
- 2150 Words
- 9 Pages
Powerful Essays -
Definitions of poverty have conventionally been alienated into two subcategories, the two being absolute poverty or relative poverty. By examining these two subdivisions it will mark what poverty means and how scientists convey them as poverty. Both classifications are purely founded on the past experiences of poverty. In our era today…
- 588 Words
- 3 Pages
Good Essays -
This essay will discuss firstly the definitions of poverty, including Seebohm Rowntree and Peter Townsend, then the causes which will cover both left and right wing theories, and finally the solutions of poverty which will look at welfare reforms.…
- 3510 Words
- 15 Pages
Powerful Essays -
Research suggests that there is an ongoing debate on what the term “poverty” means and how it can be measured. Where there seems to be a recurrent use is on the two most generic forms of poverty measurements as described in social policy literature, these being absolute poverty also referred to as subsistence (meaning a lack of basic necessities) and relative poverty, i.e. lacking of an acceptable level of resources or income as compared with others within a country (Cunningham and Cunningham, 2008).…
- 3198 Words
- 13 Pages
Best Essays -
Poverty is a complex problem that is easily understood but hard to solve. We understand that on the global scale, poverty rate is on a decline as a result of economic development that lifts millions of people out of the poverty trap. In fact, the World Bank estimated that people living on less than $1.25 a day dropped by from 1.8 billion to 1.4 billion between 1995 and 2005. Although this is a remarkable gain, it shall not understate that more than 1 billion people are still living in extreme poverty. So, there remains much work to be done to solve poverty and it helps to think of the issue in terms of the following frameworks.…
- 575 Words
- 3 Pages
Good Essays -
Poverty occurs in most parts of the world. Nevertheless, the more serious and problematical poverty takes part in the third world and the southern parts of the globe. First of all, we have to clearly define the word “poverty”. In a broad sense, it means that people within this “poverty” region are poor or have a lower average income per capita than other regions. To a deeper approach, we refer “poverty” as people have low educational backgrounds, lack of food supplies, or people with lower standard of livings, etc. According to the Webster’s New World Dictionary, the word “poverty” can be defined as: 1) the condition or quality of being poor 2) deficiency; inadequacy 3) scarcity (Webster’s p.461). Generally in this essay, we will examine the facts that lead to the poverty of these third world and southern countries.…
- 312 Words
- 2 Pages
Good Essays -
Have you ever imagined a life where you don’t have the basic essentials to send your five year old daughter to school? This is a reality for many parents living in developing countries across the globe. The definition of poverty changes every day and it vary from place to place, we all have our own definitions of poverty. But to me poverty means lacking the basic human needs which include: clean and fresh water, nutrition, health Care, education, clothing and shelter because of the inability to pay for these requirements. Poverty is not the same in every country, as classified by Jeffery D. Sachs there are three kinds of poverty that exist in our world today. They include extreme poverty, moderate poverty and relative…
- 1362 Words
- 6 Pages
Good Essays -
What is poverty? Poverty is hunger. Poverty is lack of shelter. Poverty is being sick and not being able to see a doctor. Poverty is not having access to school and not knowing how to read. Poverty is not having a job, and is fear for the future, living one day at a time. Poverty is losing a child to illness brought about by unclean water. Poverty is powerlessness, lack of representation and freedom. Poverty is affecting thousands of humans around the world everyday, it isn 't sparing anyone of a certain race, age or gender sweeping through the the world, leaving people on welfare, and without homes, or cars. A life of poverty is a difficult and psychologically draining experience. While no one wants to be poor, many people never rise above poverty…
- 2831 Words
- 12 Pages
Best Essays -
poverty? The objective of this paper is to find out the basic requirement to achieve…
- 3046 Words
- 13 Pages
Best Essays -
No matter where a person looks in the world, be it a third world country or a developed one, there are major forms of inequality; and these injustices take on many shapes. These problems all need great social change in order to improve; however, some are more urgent that others. It is this author’s belief that absolute poverty is one of them. Absolute poverty is defined as, among other things, a situation in which a person is lacking the financial means to acquire basic life necessities such as food, clothing and shelter. This problem is found in circumstantial numbers in underdeveloped countries but also in some more developed countries.…
- 1848 Words
- 5 Pages
Powerful Essays -
It has many factors that cause to poverty for a country. This happens because on this world, it has too many people but just has few jobs and lack of foods for all people to survive. Some of the causes that cause to poverty are overpopulation, education, wars, corruption, and lack of resources, politics, and natural disaster and so on.…
- 1465 Words
- 6 Pages
Better Essays