BE1WEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
vention, and a masterful political leader and campaigner.
Roosevelt's personality and character were to be important in the life of the nation. He was a man who stood out in any collection of people. He had in abundance the personal qualities necessary for political success in the United States: magnetic charm, intelligence, physical and spiritual toughness, a superb speaking voice, and a Hair for the dramatic. Perhaps the outstanding aspect of his personality was self-confidence, which his admirers found warming and his detractors found irritating. In his youth he had had the assurance that comes from secure social position and superior education. As a young man he had demonstrated to himself as well as to others that he was a capable government administrator. The bout with polio had established that he had the inner resources necessary to take personal tragedy in his stride. His career after 1928 had assured him that he had the qualities necessary to operate successfully at top levels of government and politics. And in March 1933, surely, confidence both in one's self and in the future of the nation was a quality sorely needed in the
White House.
7
Franklin D. Roosevelt and the New Deal
ALTIIOUGHHENEWDEALand Franklin D. Roosevelt were realities
T
so recently that many living Americans' knowledge of them is based upon personal memory of the 1930's rather than upon written historical accounts, the political and economic history of the decade has quickly become one of the most myth-laden aspects of the nation's past. Indeed, myths about FDR became so widespread even before he died in office in 1945 that they constituted political forces to be reckoned with, and misinterpretations of the
New Deal were prevalent well before it passed from the scene.
Most of the myths about Roosevelt and the New Deal arose from political partisanship. He was both the best loved and the most hated president of the twentieth century, and it is easy for people to believe about him what they want to believe rather than what is objectively true. Many of his admirers regard him as a knight in gleaming armor, an American St. George who slayed the dragon of economic royalism, rescued the nation from economic disaster, restored control of the country to its people, and then alerted them to the danger of fascism and saved them from Tojo,
Hitler, and Mussolini. From the oratory at AFL-CIO picnics one would gather that it was Roosevelt himself who created modern
147
I
148 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
labor unions. Negroes regard him as the best white friend of their race in their long and troubled history, with the single exception of Abraham Lincoln. Most American voters who think of themselves as liberals look back upon the New Deal as the high point of their political lives and consciously or unconsciously measure contemporary presidents and would-be presidents by an FDR yardstick. On the other side of the political fence is the legend that Roosevelt was primarily responsible for all that is distasteful and wrong in contemporary America. It was he, one hears in the locker rooms of elite country clubs, who started the nation along the road to "socialism," destroyed initiative, and created what some people call a "welfare state." There are still some people who can not bring themselves to say Roosevelt's name and refer to him as
"that man." In the late 1940's there was even a Chicagoan who tried to start a movement among consumers to refuse to accept dimes that bore FDR's image. The Roosevelt haters also measure contemporary presidents and would-be presidents of the Democratic party by an FDR yardstick. Those who are moderate in their domestic policies are 'better than FDR"; those who speak in a militant rhetoric are "as bad."
Aside from the facts that the contemporary American economy is clearly capitalistic rather than socialistic and that the federal and state governments offer fewer "welfare state" services than any major, economically developed nation in the world, the primary difficulty with these interpretations of Roosevelt, both by his admirers and detractors, is that they overemphasize his personal role and assume that he had more power than he or any other president ever had. Whether approving or disapproving of the
New Deal, the myths make Roosevelt an all-powerful giant who performed the New Deal single-handedly. Granted that FDR was the most powerful president in the nation's history, that he exercised the leverage of the White House as had never been done before, that he was a consummate molder of public opinion and manipulator of political forces, and that he was the most important political figure of his age, one must still remember that Roosevelt by no means personally brought about all the changes in
American life, even the political and economic changes, that occurred in the 1930's.
Because the United States is a political democracy and a vast and complex nation and because the major political parties are coalitions of state and regional organizations with diverse interests and ideologies, any president, including Franklin Roosevelt,
"~IJ
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW
~~~I
DEAL'
149
must to a very great extent play the role of a political broker.
Presidents, and congressmen too, are subjected to pressures from business, agriculture, and labor, from producers and consumers, from exporters and importers, from debtors and creditors, from militarists and pacifists, from the ideological left and right. The chief executive must play the broker with the various pressures exerted upon him because it is true that politics is the art of the possible. (Political middle-roaders often quote this adage as justification for inaction, but if one defines possible realistically it is a basic fact of political life. ) It is not going too far to say that government in the United States is a wonderfully complex kind of collective bargaining among all the various interests and pressures and that the occupant of the White House is the chairman of the continuous, interminable bargaining session as well as the administrator of the resulting policy.
FDR was an extraordinarily gifted political broker. To a greater degree than any other president of this century he was able to playoff one pressure against another, to yield to one kind of pressure and minimize the opposition to it, and to use his power over public opinion to strengthen those pressures he wanted strengthened. But the point is that he harmonized diverse interests in such a way as to build the most successful national political coalition in recent American history. He did not design the New
Deal; he "brokered" it. In the nature of things, the New Deal was a complex set of compromises. Roosevelt was the most important of the political figures bringing about the compromises, to be sure, but the New Deal did not spring from his mind. He was most instrumental in molding the New Deal, but the clay from which it was molded was the pressures exerted upon him.
Now, if we accept this general view of government and politics in the United States, it follows that an historian of the era will not find an unfolding of a grand plan. Indeed, if one looks in the political record for a blueprint of the New Deal, for the doctrine that guided Roosevelt and the New Dealers' actions, one can only conclude that if there was a blueprint it changed from season to season, almost from month to month. There was much in the New
Deal that was contradictory. Roosevelt zigged and zagged, ran to the left and to the right and stood in the middle. For example,
Roosevelt, as we have seen, criticized Hoover for having spent too much government money, In his first days in office FDR tried seriously to reduce federal spending. Later he resorted to vast government spending and deficit financing, then tried to balance the budget again in 1937, and later still returned to annual deficits.
150 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
Another example : the early New Deal in effect suspended the antitrust laws, but in 1938 the federal government became concerned with enforcing these laws and investigating the extent of monopoly and its abuses. As building the military and naval potential of the nation became paramount after the outbreak of war in Europe in
1939, White House concern about vigorous enforcement of the
Sherman and Clayton acts shriveled almost to nothing. Roosevelt quite obviously accepted Emerson's dictum that a foolish consistency was the hobgoblin of small minds.
This is not to say that Roosevelt was an unprincipled opportunist; it is to say that he most certainly was not doctrinaire.
Roosevelt's basic principles were widely shared ones. He believed in democracy, and he was humanitarian. He believed in employing the power of the federal government to combat the depression and to relieve those most sorely injured by it. He was willing to modify traditional relationships between government and privately owned economic enterprise in the interest of the general welfare, but he clearly was no opponent of capitalism as such.
And as for the means to be employed in working toward these general ends of recovery, relief, and reform, his were within the framework of the Constitution and representative democracy even though much that government did while he was in officewas novel.
An anecdote about Roosevelt reveals both his basic principles and his lack of doctrine. Early in his first year in office a bewildered and apparently callow and brash reporter asked, "Mr. President, are you a Communist?" Roosevelt replied that he was not.
"Are you a fascist then?" Again Roosevelt replied that he was not. "What then are you, Mr. President?" Roosevelt seemed puzzled and a little amused. "Why," he said after a moment, "I'm a Christian-and a Democrat."
The Banking Crisis
Roosevelt took the presidential oath of office in the midst of the worst financial crisis the nation had ever known. A sense of panic gripped the nation, which FDR tried to subdue with the statement in his inaugural address that "the only thing we have to fear is fear itself," and customary political tugging and hauling all but ceased. Never before during peacetime had the nation abdicated its political prerogatives to such a degree and placed governmental responsibility and power in the hands of one man.
Practically all the nation's banks were closed on Inauguration
Day, and the banks were to the economy what the heart is to the
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW
DEAL·
151
body. Business was at a standstill. One could not cash a check, make a deposit, or withdraw deposited funds. The "bank holidays" had begun in Nevada in October 1932, when the governor of the state closed the banks in order to prevent several imminent failures. Midwestern governors took similar action in February
1933, and in the first three days of March Treasury Department officials of both the old and new administrations urged other governors to declare bank holidays. The primary reason for the
Treasury's request was the alarming decline of the nation's gold reserves, the primary basis for currency. The flow of gold from the nation's banking center in New York to interior banks and to countries abroad had reduced the reserve over 71 per cent since the first of the year. Roosevelt's first task was to surmount this banking and financial crisis. Nothing more could be done until it was past.
Roosevelt's first official actions were to call a special session of
Congress' for March 9 and to issue an executive order declaring a national bank holiday. For his statutory authority Roosevelt cited a World War I measure that was not directly relevant. Treasury officials began drafting a banking bill to be introduced into the new Congress as soon as it met. They completed the drafting of the bill at 2:00 A.M. on March 9, Congress convened at noon, and Roosevelt signed the bill into law at 9:00 P.M.
This Emergency Banking Act, besides granting the President the statutory power for the executive order he already had issued, created a means to aid banks in danger of failure and provided for the reopening of only those banks that seemed in reasonably healthy condition. The measure empowered the Reconstruction
Finance Corporation to purchase preferred stock of banks and the Federal Reserve Banks to lend funds to state-chartered banks outside the Federal Reserve System. It also authorized the issue of additional Federal Reserve bank notes. The Act divided the closed banks into four categories, depending upon their degree of soundness. The strongest of them, after inspection .by examiners, were allowed to begin operations quickly ... the weakest of them, about one thousand in all, were closed permanently. By March 15 about half the banks in the country were again open for business.
They were the bigger banks and held about 90 per cent of the total banking deposits. The banking crisis had passed. On Sunday evening, March 12, in a national radio address from the White
House, Roosevelt explained the banking crisis and the action that had been taken. These "fireside chats," as he called them, proved a potent method of influencing public opinion.
152 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA , 1919-1941
The sense of urgency which gripped the country during FDR's first days in office was such that the new President could have done almost anything he wished with the nation's banks. At one extreme, he could have nationalized them or at least nationalized the important ones; at the other extreme, he could have done nothing and let the crisis run its natural course. The way actually chosen was a middle course that preserved the traditional arrangement with only minor modifications. Raymond Moley, one of FDR's early economic advisers who later parted company with the New Deal because he considered it too radical, wrote of the banking crisis and Roosevelt's actions, "If ever there was a moment when things hung in the balance, it was on March 5,1933
-when unorthodoxy would have drained the last remaining strength of the capitalistic system. Capitalism was saved in eight days." At the end of the Hoover administration an I in the first months of FDR's presidency a Senate investigation of banking and the stock market-often called the Pecora investigation after the committee's chief counsel, Ferdinand Pecora=revealed widespread abuses. Public opinion demanded reform after the March 1933 crisis was surmounted. The Glass-Steagall Banking Act of June
1933 had features designed to prevent the kind of banking malpractices the Pecora committee had discovered. This law increased the power of the Federal Reserve Banks to regulate its members, especially with respect to lending for speculative purposes. It also required that banks utterly divorce themselves from affiliated investment companies, for the Pecora committee had demonstrated that banks sometimes operated in such a way as to advance the interest of their affiliated investment firms at the risk of their depositors' security. Perhaps most important for future banking stability, the law created the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation (FDIC), a federally owned corporation, which insured deposits up to $2,500. Banks were required to take insurance policies on their deposits, for which they paid a small premium. If the bank failed, all deposits up to $2,500 would be paid off by the insurer, the FDIC. (The limit of insurance on each account went up to $5,000 in 1935 and to $10,000 in 1950.)
Knowing that their accounts were insured, depositors were unlikely to cause a bank run. Bank failures declined to insignificance. In the rest of the decade less than one tenth as many banks failed as had done so in 1933. As in several other New
Deal measures, the beneficiaries of the new law, the banks, fought the measure and argued that it was "government inter-
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL·
153
ference." The American Bankers Associationtried to prevent the bill's passage, even though it had the effect of greatly stabilizing their enterprise.
The Pecora committee also turned up evidence of stock-market rigging and of false representation of new stock issues. The Truthin-Securities Act of May 1933 required that prospective purchasers of new stock issues be fully informed about the financial condition of the firm issuing the stock,but it failed to establish an agency to enforce the law. A year later Congress established the
Securities and Exchange Commissionand granted it power to regulate the sale of all securities, whether new issues or not.
Wall Street objected to the SEC. To soften the blow, Roosevelt appointed a Boston millionaire with Wall Street connections,
Joseph P. Kennedy, to be the first SEC chairman.
With the immediate banking crisisoverby about ten days after
Roosevelt's inauguration, the new administration and Congress were ready to move on to the broaderproblem of combatting the depression. New laws creating new agencies came with great speed in the next several weeks, and the burst of legislation seemed to assure the population that Washington had at last taken decisive action. It is necessary for us to examinethese new measures of the early New Deal in a logicalpresentation rather than in chronological order, but we should rememberthat newspaper readers of
1933 were seldom able to see the contemporary events in such coherent fashion.
The First New Deal
The early New Deal was no unified,systematic,and articulated attack on the depression. It was a shotgun approach precisely because the pressures upon Congress,of Congress upon the White
House, and from the citizenry directlyupon the White House were not to be denied and the objectsof these pressures were diverse. Some parts of the populationwanted inflationary policies, and there was great support for inflation Congress, especially in among those congressmen with largely agricultural constituencies.
Some wanted massive federal spending,both to relieve poverty through federal relief and to stimulatethe economy by expanding the total market. Others wanted just the reverse: minimum spending and balanced budgets. Somewanted an over-all industrial plan. Some wanted a plan for only certainparts of the economy. In general, FDR compromisedamong these several demands,
154 .
BETWEEN THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
and the resulting first New Deal actions represented a variety of purposes and theories.
The closest thing to a systematic governmental attack on the problem of recovery was the National Industrial Recovery Act of
June 16, 1933, but even this measure was a blend of several ideas, and the administrators of the National Recovery Administration
(NRA) established by the act were never agreed in their economic philosophies. The central idea of NRA arose from the "industrial self-government" plans that had come to the fore in the last two years of the Hoover administration. But the idea of "industrial self-government," under the demands of those who urged government rather than corporation planning, of those who urged largescale government spending for public works, and of labor pressures for the right to organize and for minimum wages, was considerably modified in the resulting legislation.
The law had a curious legislative origin. At the end of the
Hoover administration Senator Hugo Black of Alabama had introduced a bill sponsored by the AFL that would have prohibited interstate commerce of goods produced by labor that worked more than thirty hours a week . The idea of the proposal was to spread the number of jobs available to a greater number of workers. Support for the scheme was widespread. On April 6, 1933, the Black bill passed the Senate. FDR and his "brain trust," as the newspapers tagged his advisers who came from university faculties, wanted a more comprehensive approach to industrial stagnation.
He sent Secretary of Labor Frances Perkins to the House Labor
Committee to head off the Black bill. Miss Perkins succeeded in her mission and proposed instead of maximum hours a scheme of minimum wages and governmentally controlled industrial production quotas. Businessmen objected vigorously to this idea. The administration then set about finding a plan that business would accept and came forward in May with a draft of the National
Industrial Recovery Act.
The bill had something for the many pressures exerted on the government. For business it had a rather heavy dose of "industrial self-government"; for those who advocated national planning there was a scheme of government approval of the codes that industry would write; for labor there was Section 7 (a), which guranteed the right to bargain collectively and to form unions of the workers' own choosing; for those demanding a large public works program there was Title II of the bill, which created the
Public Works Administration (PWA) and appropriated the huge sum of $3.3 billion.
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL·
155
The codes were the heart of the NRA. There was to be a special code written for each industry, some employing thousands of workers, such as the cotton textile industry, and some, such as the kosher poultry business, which was to bring about NRA's ultimate constitutional downfall, employing only a few hundred. Representatives from each business of an industry, as well as representatives from labor, the consuming public, and government, met and wrote a code for the industry which, after it had been approved by the NRA administrators, had the force of law. As it worked out with but few exceptions, business representatives actually wrote the codes, and they were usually from the biggest firms in the industry. Labor was usually almost voiceless, the consumer always had inadequate representation, and government representatives were without the special knowledge of the industry's detailed operations that might have made them effective. Writing the codes took time, and NRA approval of them was an enormous administrative task if they were to be reviewed carefully and effectively.
Taking advantage of the delay in getting the codes written and into operation, some manufacturers began to produce at full scale while wages and other costs were still unregulated so as to build inventories to be sold after the codes went into effect and better prices were guaranteed. To head off this self-defeating action,
Roosevelt in late July urged all employers to sign up under what was popularly called the "blanket code," to be effective until the regular code was written and approved. The blanket code prohibited the employment of children, provided for a minimum wage of forty cents an hour, and set a maximum work week of thirty-six hours for production workers and forty for clerical personnel.
Firms signed the blanket code so as to be able to display the blue eagle emblem that signified cooperation with NRA, which was thought to be necessary for the consuming public's acceptance.
But the "chiseling," to use the popular term of the day, had already done its damage. Industrial production in July rose to a little more than the 1923-1928 average, only to fall by 35 per cent by October when the blanket code became almost universal.
A great many people were unhappy with the way NRA worked.
Labor gained less than it had anticipated and said that NRA stood for "National Run Around." Small businessmen resented the domination of big business in the writing of the codes. Big businessmen complained of the concessions they had to make to labor.
Consumers were unhappy about the higher prices they had to pay for goods. And there was considerable unrest among those who
156 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
feared the power of concentrated big business because NRA suspended the antitrust laws. Congress had created NRA for only a two-year period, and it remained to be seen what Congress would do when asked to renew the legislation. But the Supreme Court intervened on May 25, 1935, and in Schechter v. United States unanimously declared NRA unconstitutional. The Court's primary objection was that the Constitution invested only Congress with the power to legislate and that the codes were actually legislation.
Some New Dealers thought that the Court in the Schechter case had saved the administration from further embarrassment, but
Roosevelt was greatly disappointed. As he anticipated after the
Court's decision, child labor increased, as did unemployment, while wages declined. Yet NRA obviously had not effected full recovery, and many people were concerned lest it lead to development of the kind of formal corporate state then in force in Mussolini's Italy. After adjusting to the idea of the death of NRA,
Roosevelt abandoned the idea of industrial self-government and never returned to it.
Three other kinds of measures or programs of the early New
Deal must be considered: monetary manipulation to bring a degree of inflation, federal spending for public works and relief, and special agricultural recovery legislation. The political pressures for all three were overwhelming.
Inflation through monetary manipulation had been a demand of agricultural America during depressions from the colonial period forward and had been especially strong in the late nineteenth century. Roosevelt did not agree altogether with the inflationists in Congress-he was happy that Senator Burton K.
Wheeler's bill putting forward the 1896 Bryanite demand for free and unlimited coinage of silver at a ratio of 16 to 1 with gold was defeated in the Senate, although by only ten votes-but he recognized that the depression had brought a severe deflation and he was willing to resort to a degree of inflation to offset it. Roosevelt was further bothered by the international implications of an inHationary program. He had pledged support of the World Economic
Conference which was to meet in London in June 1933 and which, among other things, would endeavor to stabilize the world's currencies. This put FDR in just the kind of position he hated: he had to decide between support of the conference or a degree of inflation. He could not have both. After vacillating until the last minute, he decided for inflation and scuttled the conference.
There were two main aspects of New Deal monetary manipulation: changing the gold content of the dollar and a silver pur-
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL •
157
chase program. Through a series of executive orders and laws in the first two months of the administration the United States in effect abandoned the gold standard. An executive order prohibited the hoarding of gold, prohibited the redemption of currency for gold, and forbade the export of gold without Treasury permission. Then in October 1933 FDR instructed the Reconstruction
Finance Corporation to begin buying gold on the world market above the world price. This meant that the gold content of the dollar was reduced by as much as the government paid above the world price. In January 1934 FDR requested Congress to pass the Gold Reserve Act, which became effective at the end of the month and authorized the chief executive to fix the gold content of the dollar between fifty and sixty cents. Roosevelt fixed the gold price at which the United States would buy at an even $35 an ounce. The price of gold when he took office had been $20.67.
In other words, the dollar had been devalued roughly 40 per cent in terms of gold, thus making it 40 per cent easier for foreigners to purchase American products.
The Silver Purchase Act of June 1934 also had an inflationary purpose, but it was largely a raid by the nation's silver interests.
The law required the Treasury to buy silver until its supply of the metal equaled one fourth of its total metallic reserve, or until the price of silver reached $1 .29 an ounce, and to issue silver certificates and silver dollars on the purchased metal. The stated purpose of the act was to increase prices until they reached 1926 levels, but despite the law and all the other New Deal measures prices did not rise to that level until after Pearl Harbor.
Expanded federal budgets probably did more to bring about recovery than did monetary manipulation. Federal spending for relief of the indigent was not only humanitarian, it was also economically stimulating because it directly increased total purchasing power. This kind of government stimulation of the economy was the reverse of the "trickle down" aid that the RFC had employed under Hoover and continued to practice under Roosevelt.
The first New Deal relief act was the creation of the Civilian Conservation Corps in late March 1933. The CCC took 250,000 young men from relief families, put them to work under War Department supervision at reforestation and other conservation projects, and paid them $30 a month, of which $25 went directly home to their families. When the CCC stopped in 1940 two and a quarter million young men had served in the organization. For relief of others Congress created the Federal Emergency Relief
Administration (FERA) in May 1933 with an appropriation of
158 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
$500 million, but in the fall of that year it became apparent that a larger program would be necessary to get relief families through the winter.
The administration had hoped that the Public Works Administration, headed by Secretary of the Interior Harold L. Ickes and created under Title II of NIRA, would be in full operation by the winter of 1933-1934, enough to employ thousands of men on public works such as new schools and highways. Ickes, however, was so determined that the money be spent wisely and carefully that
PWA did not quickly put large numbers of men to work. Consequently in November 1933 FDR took some of the PWA funds, created the Civil Works Administration (CWA), installed Harry
Hopkins as its head, and instructed him to spend the funds as quickly as possible so that men on relief could be put to work.
Within two months Hopkins had four million people working on
CWA projects. Many of the projects were ill conceived, but CWA did get dollars into the hands of families that needed it badly and thereby stimulated the whole economy as well. When the winter was over FDR closed down CWA, and Congress reinvigorated
FERA with another large appropriation. Undoubtedly, federal relief in 1933 and 1934 greatly helped poor families, but the whole relief program was makeshift and temporary until 1935 when
Congress created the Works Progress Administration.
Public works, as distinct from make-work projects primarily for relief purposes, made a lasting contribution to the country's welfare. The PWA ultimately created over four million manhours of work and built millions of dollars' worth of roads, schools, post offices, courthouses, and other public buildings. The most ambitious New Deal public work was the Tennessee Valley
Authority (TVA) , the brain-child of Senator Norris. TVA expanded from the Muscle Shoals installation into a huge and complex system of dams that not only provided millions of kilowatt hours of electricity but made possible for the first time a systematic way to control floods in the valley and to help control them downstream in the Mississippi system. As inexpensive electric power became available the Tennessee valley increasingly became industrialized, and the living standards of the region, once near the lowest in the nation, significantly improved.
Even with a degree of inflation and federal relief, it was apparent that special legislation for agriculture was essential just as the
NRA was special legislation for industry. Increasing the amount of agricultural credit available was one necessary action-this was accomplished by the Emergency Farm Mortgage Act and the
FRANKLIN
D. ROOSEVELT
AND THE NEW DEAL·
159
Farm Credit Act in the spring of 1933 and the Frazier-Lemke
Farm Bankruptcy Act a year later-but the essential problem was to increase the prices of farm products so that farming would once again become a profitable enterprise. The scheme adopted by the
New Deal, as embodied in the Agricultural Adjustment Act of
May 12, 1933, set the pattern of farm policy that the federal government has followed with some modifications ever since. The
AAA was not a new idea. It was the culmination of various agricultural proposals going as far back as those of the Populists of the 1890's, and in some respects it was the logical next step after the Federal Farm Board experiment of the Hoover administration.
The object of the AAA was to bring about a better balance between the prices of agricultural and industrial products, to bring them to the same ratio that had existed from 1909 to 1914. This ratio, or parity as it was generally called, was to be achieved, it was hoped, by restricting agricultural production. In other words, the method was to increase prices by reducing supply. Individual farmers of basic crops made agreements with the AAA in which they agreed to take some of their land out of production and receive a subsidy from the AAA for the land thus left fallow. The
AAA also had authority to buy up surplus agricultural commodities, or to lend funds to producers with the crops as collateral, to peg farm prices. A special tax on processors of agricultural products financed the whole AAA program. The processors, of course, passed the tax on to the consumer. In 1936 the Supreme
Court declared AAA unconstitutional because of this special tax, and Congress subsequently rewrote the law in a manner that met the constitutional objection.
In a narrow sense, AAA was successful. Helped along by droughts that also lowered production, AAA succeeded in approximately doubling the price of wheat, com, and cotton by 1935.
Total farm income increased. by about 53 per cent. But on the other hand the program had deep-rooted difficulties. Crop restriction by putting some land out of production was less than fully effective because farmers could use more fertilizer on the land actually being used and thereby increase their yields. The system also had an unfortunate side effect on cotton-farming sharecroppers. Landlords sometimes failed to share AAA benefits with their tenants and often used their government checks to buy tractors and other equipment which tended to make sharecroppers obsolete. Forced off the land and having no other vocational skills, displaced sharecroppers were a serious social problem until full employment during the war alleviated their plight.
160 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA , 1919-1941
But the most distressing feature of the program was that it reduced the amount of food and fiber available when people were hungry and ragged, and the idea of calculated wasted potential went against the grain. Yet in more than a generation no one has come forth with a better proposal that is acceptable to both farmer and consumer.
The Second New Deal
In the late winter of 1934-1935 any objective observer would have had to recognize that in Roosevelt's first two years there had been an improvement in the nation's economic condition. Most importantly, the banks were open and functioning normally and the panic that had characterized Hoover's last and Roosevelt's first weeks had disappeared. There was less unemployment than there had been in March 1933, the farmers were not in as desperate a condition, and the poor were not so close to utter disaster as they had been when Roosevelt took office. Yet the observer would also have noted that the depression was by no means over.
Unemployment stood at about ten million, and the number of those who had jobs was only at about the level of 1932. Young people coming into the labor market still went for months, even years, before they were able to find even a poor job. Businessmen, or most of them, did not face annual deficits as they had just two or three years before, but none of them was so foolish as to describe business conditions as good. And reformers, those who had hoped that the New Deal would be the triumph of progressivism, could point to little in the New Deal record that warmed their hearts. The banking legislation, the tax act of 1934 which closed some income-tax loopholes permitting men such as J. P. Morgan,
Jr. to escape paying income taxes altogether, the SEC, and the
TVA were about all the New Deal measures so far that clearly had reform as their primary intent.
The political situation had changed drastically since FDR's inauguration. The urgency of the economic crisis had been so severe in the New Deal's earliest weeks and many Republicans had been so demoralized by recent events that Roosevelt enjoyed something close to a political honeymoon at first. For example, when the
Emergency Banking Act was before the House of Representatives on March 9, 1933, the Republican floor leader told his colleagues, "The house is burning down, and the President of the
United States says this is the way to put out the fire." The
House went on to approve the measure after only forty minutes'
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL •
161
debate. The Republican press was usually gentle with the new
President. The New York Daily News, part of the Patterson-MeCormick group of newspapers, even organized a campaign for raising funds to build a swimming pool in the White House.
Roosevelt enjoyed swimming, and it was about the only exercise that his paralyzed legs permitted. The Hearst newspapers, nominally Democratic because of their owner's adventures in that party, supported Roosevelt in 1933. Soon they would become shrill critics of the White House editorially.
In 1934, conservative newspaper attacks on the New Deal and the organization of the American Liberty League in August of that year indicated that the right wing had recovered from its depression shell-shock and was prepared for counterattack. The honeymoon was obviously over. Wealthy men, most of them in the Du
Pont family or officials in the Du Pont-controlled General Motors
Corporation, financed the Liberty League, but a group of conservative Democrats who had once led their party got most of the publicity. Al Smith was the prize speaker for the Liberty League, and he categorically described the New Deal's laws as "socialism:'
The Liberty League pulled out all the stops for Republican candidates in the 1934 elections but was unable to bring the party through. Republicans lost fourteen more House seats in that election and won only eleven of the disputed senatorships. There were only seven Republican governors after the 1934 elections.
Roosevelt regretted the end of the truce by the political right although he probably anticipated it. He was more seriously concerned with what was happening within his own coalition. Democratic members of Congress, under pressure from home, were pushing for reform of the economy as well as greater relief and bolder recovery policies. Significant numbers of voters who had been for FDR in 1932 believed that the New Deal had not yet done enough and they were increasingly following new leaders, some of them with odd programs, who demanded more radical departures. In the upper Mississippi Valley progressive Democrats and La Follette Republicans kept talking of a new national
Farmer-Labor party although they always stopped short of forming one and deserting the Roosevelt coalition. Labor-union leaders, not yet as strong as they would be after the great organizing campaigns of 1936 and 1937 but still influential, frequently expressed disillusionment with FDR. Most alarming to FDR were
Upton Sinclair's capture of the Democratic party in California, the growing strength of Senator Huey Long's Share Our Wealth organization, and the immense popularity of the Townsend plan.
162 . BETWEEN THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
Sinclair, a well-known novelist and a member of the Socialist party for most of his life, entered the Democratic primary for governor in 1934 and ran on a program he called EPIC, End Poverty in California. EPIC proposed a $50-a-month pension for the indigent over age sixty and a system of "production for use" workshops for the unemployed, partly producer-cooperative, partly socialistic in scope . Despite great opposition from the party machine, Sinclair won the primary rather easily. In the general election, the campaign against Sinclair was intense, heavily financed by Hollywood figures, and low in its tactics. FDR refused to support Sinclair, and prominent Golden State Democrats worked for the Republican candidate. Although he lost to the Republican,
Sinclair still ran a strong race. Huey Long was the epitome of the back-country demagogic politician, but in the mid-1930's political demagogues found economic radicalism rather than anti-Bolshevism or racism the best way to attract followers. Long's slogan was "Every Man a King," and he promised everyone a homestead worth $5,000 and a $2,500 annual income to be derived from the confiscation of large fortunes. Francis E. Townsend, a retired physician of Long Beach, California, proposed the Old Age Revolving Pension. The plan called for a $200 pension to be paid to all unemployed people over sixty, with the requirement that the recipients spend the entire amount within a month in order to be eligible for the next payment. Townsend thought a 2 per cent tax on all financial transactions would be sufficient to finance the scheme. The plan was very popular among the aged all over the country, and in 1934 the Townsendites succeeded in electing a congressman from southern California. That some of these proposals were odd, perhaps even dangerous, only more sharply dellneated the widespread dissatisfaction many voters felt toward the accomplishments of the New Deal.
With the political right having come back to life and with apparently large sections of Roosevelt's electoral support deserting toward the left or the pseudo-left, it was obvious that the administration must change direction if it were to remain politically strong. Recovering the right was probably impossible, but if it could be accomplished it could be only at the expense of greater defections to the left. The only thing to do was for the administration to shift toward the left and take the wind out of the sails that had been bearing men such as Sinclair, Long, and Townsend with such vigor. FDR debated with himself for weeks in the late winter, but in the spring of 1935 he began to accept, even began to urge, proposals that had been advocated by the more progressive
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELTAND THE NEW DEAL·
163
members of Congress for many months. The result was that in
1935 Congress passed and the President signed a most unusual slate of progressive legislation. The year 1935 may be said to have been progressivism's high tide.
The shift in the way the White House was leaning was indicated by word passed to Congress that the President was for a great increase in spending for public works and relief. One of the conservative arguments against the New Deal was that it cost too much and failed to balance the federal budget. Many New Dealers argued that large-scale government spending was necessary "to prime the pump." Economists who followed the theories of Britain's John Maynard Keynes argued that government dollars spent had a "multiplier effect," that for every dollar spent by the government there would be an increase in GNP between two and three dollars. They also argued that federal deficits were at least in the short run beneficial during depressions because through bankpurchased government bonds they increased money in circulation and loosened credit.
In early April 1935, Congress passed the Emergency Relief Appropriation Act with an appropriation of $4,888,000,000, a new high for public works and relief. The following month FDR established the Works Progress Administration (WPA) under the act and put Harry Hopkins in charge. Most of the money went for construction and conservation. Before the end of 1936, 1,497 new water-works had been completed, hundreds of new roads and sewage-disposal plants, and scores of bridges, levees, and airports.
About one fifth of the funds went for community-service projects of all kinds, some of which employed jobless artists, musicians, and actors. In the six years that the WPA was active it employed over eight million different individuals (about one sixth of the labor force) and spent $11.4 billion. WPA wages varied according to degree of skill required and from region to region, but the average monthly wage in 1936 was $52.14.
The same law that created the WPA also provided for the National Youth Administration (NYA) . NYA's main purpose was to provide part-time employment for students in high school and college, but it also had a small program for young people who were not in school. Huge numbers of students were thus enabled to continue their education and remain off the labor market. In 1940,
100,000 college undergraduates and over 1,500 graduate students were on NYA rolls. Congress in 1935 also doubled its appropriation for the cec.
A 1935 law that had far-reaching implications for the oper-
164 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
ation of the economy was the National Labor Relations Act, often called the Wagner Act for its sponsor, Senator Robert F. Wagner of New York. At first trade unionists had been elated by the labor provisions of NRA, but the law in practice fell far short of their expectations. There were two difficulties with Section 7(a) from the unions' point of view: a company union (not a genuine union, but one dominated and financed by the employer) enabled companies to circumvent the purpose of the law, and such unions more than doubled in number during the NRA years; and the law permitted more than one collective-bargaining agent for men in the same shop, even those doing the same work, which enabled employers to playoff one union against another. Labor unions grew in strength under NRA, but the basic labor law was a continual frustration. Throughout 1934 Senator Wagner worked for a new labor law more conducive to union growth and strength. He got no support from the White House and was unable to get his bill through without the President's help. He reintroduced his bill in the new Congress. After he had successfully fought off amendments to the bill that would have weakened it considerably, the Senate passed the proposal on May 16 with only twelve dissenting votes. Still FDR offered the measure no support. On May 24, three days before the
Supreme Court voided NRA, Roosevelt at last gave the Wagner bill encouragement, probably because he thought it would pass
Congress anyway. Less than a month later the House passed the bill. Although businessmen were almost unanimously opposed to it, the House approved it overwhelmingly without even a roll call.
The Wagner Act created the National Labor Relations Board and asserted that all employees had a right to join or form a union and through the union to bargain collectively with their employers. A union that won a majority of employee votes in a
NLRB-conducted secret-ballot election became the workers' sole bargaining agent, and the law required employers to bargain with the union in good faith. The law also enumerated and prohibited employer "unfair practices," among them firing men for union activity and subsidizing company unions. For the first time, federal law was favorable to trade-union growth, and unions quickly capitalized on the opportunity and organized basic industries such as automobiles and steel.
Another 1935 law at least equal to the Wagner Act in its modification of the economy was the Social Security Act, which became law in August. The idea behind social security was by no means new. Theodore Roosevelt had advocated old-age pensions in
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW
DEAL·
165
1912, and by the 1930's about half the states had some kind of a pension or unemployment-compensation system. Very few of the state laws even approached adequacy, and most were of little help at all. Popular demand for a social security system was strong, particularly after the Townsend plan caught the imagination of aged people. In 1934 Congress could not decide between two social security bills, and Roosevelt proposed a special committee to study the problem and report back to Congress. The committee made its report in January 1935. That Congress would pass some kind of legislation soon was a foregone conclusion; the only real disagreement was over details. In the final votes only six senators and thirty-three representatives opposed the law.
A very complex law, the Social Security Act primarily provided for old-age pensions and compensations for the unemployed.
Through a payroll tax on both employers and employees-at first only 1 per cent on the first $3,000 of employee income, but to be gradually increased-the act created a fund from which retired workers aged sixty-five or more would receive monthly pensions.
The first payments were to begin in 1942 and would be $10 at a minimum and $85 at a maximum, depending upon how much the retired worker and his employer had contributed. For those who had already retired and were at least sixty-five, the federal government would share the costs of pensions with the states. The unemployment-compensation provisions also involved federal-state cooperation, but the law established a minimum weekly compensation and the minimum number of weeks during which those who lost jobs could receive payments.
The original law was far from satisfactory to everyone. Farm laborers, domestic and casual workers, public employees, and those on the payrolls of educational and religious institutions did not come under the provisions of the act, and the old-age pensions were inadequate for a decent living standard if the beneficiary had no other income. The unemployment-compensation provisions were of no help to those who were already unemployed.
One had first to get a job and then lose it to receive compensation.
But, clearly, once the basic idea of federal social security was enacted the benefits could be increased and extended to further categories of employees, and the law has since been amended several times. The new labor and social security laws were the later New
Deal's most basic reform legislation, but there were other reforms as well. Marriner S. Eccles, whom FDR had appointed chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, urged passage of a law to enlarge
166 .
[
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
the powers of the Board so that it could more readily and more effectively take compensatory action against fluctuations in the business cycle. The Banking Act of 1935 did not contain all that
Eccles wished, but it was the most important revision of the Federal Reserve System since it had been established in the early
Wilson administration. The law transferred from the twelve regional Reserve Banks to the central Board the power to raise or lower the discount rate and gave the Board additional power to determine the reserve requirements of all banks in the system and to conduct its open-market operations. The law also extended the kinds of commercial paper against which Federal Reserve notes could be issued and raised the maximum FDIC-insured account to $5,000. The law has since been used many times to offset cyclical tendencies, to raise the discount rate when undesired inflation seemed likely, for example, and to lower it and thereby make credit easier when a downswing in the cycle seemed imminent.
A new tax law in 1935, passed after FDR sent Congress a message in which he urged tax revision "encouraging a wider distribution of wealth ," earned the vigorous opposition of conservatives who called it a "soak the rich" measure. The new law by no means made it impossible to amass great wealth nor to pass it on to heirs, but it did increase inheritance taxes sharply and established a new surtax on net incomes of over $50,000 a year.
The reform measure of 1935 that had the most difficult road to passage was a law passed in August forbidding further development of holding-company empires in public utilities, such as the
Insull system, and providing for the gradual breakup of holdingcompany pyramids that already existed in public utilities. Lobbyists for power companies were extremely active in resisting the law, but when Senator Black brought forward the information that the flood of telegrams against the bill received by members of
Congress were actually from lobbyists and not from those whose names appeared on them, the lobbyists received a setback. The law empowered the SEC to limit holding companies to a single integrated system with no more than one layer of holding company. The Rural Electrification Authority (REA) created by executive order in May 1935 with already appropriated funds did much to improve living conditions and lighten work loads on the nation's farms. At that time, only 10 per cent of American farms had electricity, less than most European countries, Within a few years REA electric cooperatives and privately owned electric com-
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL'
167
panies, spurred at last to action, brought electricity to all but the most remote farm areas. Electric automatic pumps on farm wells made running water feasible-no inconsiderable aspect of the narrowing differences between urban and rural life.
The New Deal's shift toward the left brought the results anticipated. The electorate, it became obvious in the next elections, overwhelmingly approved the measures and ceased to follow leftof-New Deal leaders in significant numbers. Sinclair's EPIC faded to complete obscurity. The Townsend movement continued but with less steam. Long's movement failed to survive his assassination in September 1935. Roosevelt's conservative opposition was more vigorous than ever, despite FDR's announcement in the fall of 1935 of a "breathing spell" for business, but the President well understood that he and his party would have received few votes from conservatives in any case. But before considering the 1936 elections let us look briefly at the methods the New Deal took to alleviate the depression through foreign policy.
New Deal Foreign Policy
Remarkably seldom do those who study the past recognize that certain foreign policies of the Roosevelt administration were part of its program to effect economic recovery. A nation's foreign affairs, one must remember, are not conducted in a vacuum; domestic conditions and pressures play a major role in determining a country's policies with other nations.
Until at least the late 1930's, when questions of war and peace came to dominate the New Deal's conduct of foreign affairs, the administration's main concern in foreign policy was to increase markets for American products abroad. Actually, in one way of looking at it, the whole attack on the Great Depression was one of increasing markets, both domestic and foreign. If the United
States could sell wheat or steel or automobiles abroad, American investors got a better return and labor had jobs. With the advent of the depression American exports had shrunk very badly. Exports had amounted to $5,240,995,000 in 1929; they fell to $1,611,016,000 in 1932, the lowest year, a decline of roughly two thirds. (Imports declined similarly. The United States had an excess of exports over imports throughout the depression, although in some years the excess was quite small.) Both the administration and business leaders recognized that regaining these foreign markets would have a stimulating effect upon the domestic economy. The Roosevelt administration's means to achieve this goal were many, among
168 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
others recognition of theretofore unrecognized foreign regimes so as to facilitate commercial relations, loans with which to purchase
American products, and, most important, a new scheme of tariffs.
President Wilson had refused to extend diplomatic recognition to the new regime in Russia after the Bolshevik revolution in 1917, and each of his successors in the 1920's had continued the nonrecognition policy. Hoover had been under some pressure to recognize the Soviet Union because there were some businessmen who wanted to sell their products to the Communists and thought that regular diplomatic relations would facilitate commerce, but
Hoover had committed himself against recognition and would do no more than arrange for the RFC to underwrite some cotton exports to Russia. Roosevelt had made no commitment against recognition, and a few weeks after his inauguration he began correspondence looking toward formal recognition. FDR, of course, had more than commercial considerations in mind, but hoped-for sales to the Soviets were no minor motivating factor. Formal recognition came on November 16, 1933. Early the next year the administration created the Export-Import Bank, under authority of the National Industrial Recovery Act and financed originally with RFC funds. Ex-Im, as it is commonly called, began to underwrite the financing for sales to the Soviets. Despite the expectations of 1933 and 1934, however, the Russian market did not develop significantly. The Russians were balky in the negotiations over the bonds owned by Americans that the Czarist government had issued, the USSR refusing to honor the prerevolutionary debt, and relatively little American production went to Russia until the
Lend-Lease exports of World War II.
Ex-1m lay dormant after the Russian debt negotiations fell through, but Congress revived it in 1935 on a two-year basis.
Congress subsequently extended its life periodically, and Ex-Im has grown into a major international credit agency that today materially stimulates American sales abroad. It became a permanent agency in 1945. It is important to realize that Ex-Im foreign loans are not sums that the receiving nation is free to spend indiscriminately and wherever it chooses. The purposes of the loans are spelled out in detail, and all, or practically all, of the loan is in the form of credits from American firms. Thus loans extended by an agency of the federal government are used to purchase American production. In 1938 Ex-Irn began to make development loans to economically underdeveloped nations, which to the degree that the loans led to an increase in the bon-owing nation's GNP made further exports possible. Some Ex-Im loans
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL'
169
were for military strategic purposes; a 1938 loan to China of $25 million was for the Burma Road, which was essential in the war against Japan. Ex-Im was not the only federal agency engaged in foreign loans designed to stimulate American foreign sales. In
1934, for example, the RFC lent China $15 million with which to purchase United States cotton, wheat, and flour. By the end of
1941 the RFC had authorized the spending of $47,301,000 for financing exports of agricultural surpluses.
.
The reciprocal trade agreement program was the New Deal's most ambitious effort to increase American foreign markets. The enabling law, passed in June 1934, expressly stated in its preamble that its purpose was to expand "foreign markets for the products of the United States." Reciprocity, an old idea, was a pet project of Secretary of State Cordell Hull, who was long an advocate of low tariffs. To lower tariffs across the board while jobs were scarce would have been political dynamite, but the more selective tariff reduction of reciprocal agreements was less likely to arouse domestic opposition, and shrewdly bargained agreements were often a considerable boon to American exports. Even so, those who advocated traditionally high tariffs objected strenuously. The
Republican platform of 1936 singled out, of all the New Deal's measures, only the reciprocity program for repeal .
The Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934 granted the executive branch the power to negotiate arrangements with other countries in which American customs duties could be lowered by as much as 50 per cent in exchange for reciprocal reductions by the other powers. Such agreements were not treaties, did not require ratification by the Senate, and could go into effect immediately upon their signing. The original act of 1934 authorized such agreements for a period of three years, and Congress thereafter extended the measure for two or three years at a time. The problem in negotiating the agreements was to persuade the other nation to reduce its duties on products that the United States had in abundance and for which it needed a bigger market and, in exchange, to lower American duties on articles that would not be in competition with domestic production. Of course, the same problem presented itself to the other power at the negotiating table, and the negotiations were slow and difficult. Nevertheless, by
1942 the United States had signed reciprocal trade agreements with twenty-three nations, largely with Latin American countries but also with Canada (1936 and 1940), Sweden (1935), France
(1936), and Great Britain (1939).
One feature of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act led to a
170 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
general lowering of the tariff: the law provided that agreements contain a "most favored nation" clause. Thus, any lowering of duties arrived at by an agreement between the United States and any second power would automatically be extended, for the products covered in the agreement, to all other powers of the world except those that the chief executive stated were discriminatory in their commercial relations with the United States. An example: the 1936 agreement with Brazil lowered the American duty on coffee; it thereby decreased the American duty on coffee imported from all other nations that had "most-favored-nation" status.
Roosevelt excepted only Nazi Germany (and Australia very brieRy) from the general decrease in tariff rates emanating from trade agreements, and the agreements therefore worked to bring about a significant scaling down of the United States tariff wall.
Calculating how much precisely the trade agreements reduced the general tariff level was a formidable mathematical exercise, but in
1942 the government estimated that the agreements, together with the generalizing effect for "most favored nations," had reduced the tariff level by 29 per cent since 1933.
It is impossible to say exactly how much reciprocal trade agreements extended American markets because there were too many variables, too many other forces operating which also extended the export market . But the market did increase. Exports increased to $3,349,167 in 1937, fell off a little in the recession of
1938, and then climbed again to $4,021,146 in 1940, the last full year before the beginning of Lend-Lease. Exports of most nations increased simultaneously, of course, as the world depression became less serious, but it is significant that until the recession
American exports increased more rapidly than did those of oth~r nations. In other words, the United States increased its share of the world's markets, and the increase probably was due to advantages bargained for in the trade agreements.
Although much that has been written about Roosevelt's wellpublicized Good Neighbor policy toward Latin America has emphasized United States diplomatic maturity and its growing sense of international responsibility, an emphasis that is valid, those who developed and directed the policy nevertheless had a strong concern for American economic interest. United States trade with Latin American nations declined approximately 70 per cent between 1929 and 1932. Growing anti-Yanqui sentiment in
Latin America threatened North American investments and discouraged them for the future. Quite obviously, if the United
States during the Great Depression had continued Theodore
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL·
171
Rooseveltian, interventionist, and high-handed Latin American policies, it would not have been doing itself an economic favor.
The Hoover administration moved in the direction of the
Good Neighbor policy with its publication of the Clark memorandum on the Monroe Doctrine in 1930. This memorandum omitted reference to the Theodore Roosevelt corollary to the doctrine. But the United States still had not renounced armed intervention in Latin American nations on other grounds until the
Montevideo Conference of American States in December 1933, where Secretary of State Hull explicitly renounced the right to intervene. Immediately after the end of the conference, FDR said publicly that opposition to armed intervention was "... the definite policy of the United States from now on." In 1936 the
State Department agreed to a protocol that forbade intervention
"directly or indirectly, and for whatever reason," and the Senate approved the action.
Actions accompanied words. Washington refrained from armed intervention in Cuba in that island's troubles in 1933 and abrogated the Platt Amendment the following year. Also in 1933 the Roosevelt administration agreed to withdraw American marines from Haiti, and when the last unit left the following summer it was the first time in decades that marines had not been garrisoned somewhere in a Latin American republic. The biggest test of the Good Neighbor policy came with Mexico in 1938 and thereafter. The Mexican government in early 1938 expropriated oil lands owned by American and other foreign firms. Although the pressures on the White House were intense, the administration stuck to its announced Latin American policy and countenanced the expropriation, which was entirely legal.
The Good Neighbor policy was a success both in terms of the general national interest and of economic interest. After Pearl
Harbor the Latin American republics, with the exception of Argentina, stood by the United States and helped in the war against the Axis. If there had been a lack of Latin American cooperation or if that area had been actually hostile, the American war effort would have been severely handicapped and complicated. Sales to and investments in Latin America did not significantly help the
United States to emerge from the depression, but trade with the
Latins did increase. Exports to the Latin American nations more than quadrupled between 1932 and 1941, and although direct
American investments there did not reach the 1929 high until the 1940's they climbed from their low point of the early depression.
172 ."BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
Democratic High Tide
After the session of Congress that had passed the unprecedented slate of progressive legislation in 1935, both Republicans and
Democrats looked forward to the 1936 elections. Republicans, or at least most of them, hoped for a GOP victory that would mean repudiation of the New Deal, an end of further New Deal measures, and a repeal of some already enacted; Democrats sought the electorate's affirmation, and at least some Democrats thought a victory would be the signal for another round of reform.
The Republicans met first in 1936. The problem of their ticket was serious since they had no nationally popular leader seeking the nomination. The convention nominated Governor Alfred M.
Landon of Kansas, who had attracted attention by winning despite the Democratic landslide in 1934. Governor Landon had supported the Bull Moose rebellion in 1912, but his more conservative cohorts were willing to forgive that indiscretion. Landon had little personal flair or political magnetism, and the convention nominated for the second spot Colonel Frank Knox, publisher of a Chicago newspaper, to lend dash to the ticket. The platform was also a problem. Suspecting that the New Deal laws were basically popular, most Republicans were hesitant to call for their repeal. Their platform criticized Democratic administration of the laws, but did not call for their repeal (except, as previously noted, for the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act).
FDR's renomination was a foregone conclusion. The Philadelphia convention was no more than a huge Roosevelt rally.
Roosevelt in his acceptance speech seemed to endorse the idea of further reform when he condemned "economic royalists" who sought to establish "industrial dictatorship." The convention endorsed the New Deal, as everyone expected it to do, and renominated the conservative John N. Garner for the vice-presidency.
Both candidates ran hard, and the campaign generated a great deal of excitement. Roosevelt upon several occasions answered
Republican charges that he was against capitalism with assertions that he and his party had actually saved that economic system. "It was this administration which saved the system of private profit and free enterprise after it had been dragged to the brink of ruin by these same leaders who now try to scare you." Landon had difficulty with his campaign. Actually not an extreme conservative at all and calculating that an appeal to right-wing sentiments
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL·
173
would only lose votes, Landon was restrained in his criticisms of the Democratic record. But Republican National Chairman John
D. M. Hamilton did his best to leave voters with the impression that a Landon victory would mean wiping the New Deal from the books and that a Democratic success would mean the end of political democracy in the United States. Maine in those days voted for state and congressional offices in September-it did not change to conform with the rest of the nation until after World War II-and when the Republicans won in Maine they raised their old slogan,
"As Maine goes, so goes the nation." The Republicans were actually optimistic. The Literary Digest poll, conducted by postcards with names gathered from telephone directories and automobile registration records, indicated that Landon would win. An overwhelming majority of the nation's newspapers supported the Republican candidate.
Election day was a shock to the Republican party. Roosevelt won the greatest victory of any presidential candidate since James
Monroe in 1820. He carried every state except Maine and Vermont-Democratic wags rephrased the GOP slogan to "As Maine goes, so goes Vermont"-even defeating Landon in the governor's home state. With 36.5 per cent of the popular vote Landon had done better than his eight electoral votes made it appear, but the
Republicans could find little solace in the returns. They had taken a bad licking in state and congressional races as well.
Some aspects of the election deserve special consideration.
Roosevelt's popularity was obvious from even a superficial examination of the election results, but closer examination revealed that he and his party were especially popular among those parts of the population that had been hardest hit by the depression. The
Literary Digest poll had been so far from accurate largely because its sampling system had ignored those too poor to own automobiles and maintain telephones. Precincts in working-class neighborhoods, especially in the big cities, went for Roosevelt more heavily than did the nation as a whole. Republicans charged that the Democrats had used WPA to coerce voters. Actually, there had been a few cases of Democrats using WPA for political purposes, but Hopkins had been quick to stop such practices wherever he had found them. Most of the WPA employees did vote for Franklin D. Roosevelt and other Democratic candidates, but this was mainly because they calculated that the Democratic party had done more for them and for recovery generally than had the Republican party or than the Republicans would if they should
174 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
again become the majority party.
Organized labor's role in the campaign was a new development. John L. Lewis and Sidney Hillman of the newly formed
CIO established Labor's Non-Partisan League to promote FDR's campaign and to help friends of labor in congressional races.
Never before had labor unions been so active in a national election, never so generous with manpower and financial contributions. The size of labor's support indicated that Roosevelt had been successful in adding another element to the Democratic coalition, especially in the industrial states, and in time to come the alliance of the Democratic party with organized labor would become even stronger.
Still another significant aspect of the 1936 election was the change in the political affiliation of the Negro voter. Since the
Civil War, the Negro vote, what there was of it, had always gone to Republicans because theirs was the party of Lincoln. But most
New Deal administrators had treated Negroes fairly, the Roosevelt family had entertained Negro leaders in the White House to a far greater extent than had earlier first families, and most Negroes who voted-in the North and West-were industrial workers, and industrial workers of all races were predominantly
Democratic. Also, the Republicans in 1928, in an effort to win southern white votes, had ignored southern Negro Republican leadership in favor of the "lily whites." The shift had started to reveal itself in 1934. In 1928 a predominantly Negro district on
Chicago's South Side had elected a Republican, Oscar De Priest, to Congress, the first Negro to serve there since Reconstruction.
The same district in 1934 elected a Negro Democrat, Arthur W.
Mitchell, who had been a registered Republican as late as 1930.
The 1936 elections demonstrated the political astuteness of the
New Deal's shift to the left for a few months in 1935. The left-ofFDR forces had lost momentum when Roosevelt accepted their most popular programs, or parts of them, and the pseudo-left demagogues who tried to keep the Huey Long movement going with the Union party came out badly on election day. Roosevelt had put together an extraordinary political coalition: southern traditionalists, big-city political machines, industrial workers of all races, trade unionists, and many depression-hit farmers. With such majorities as the Democrats had (all but 19 seats in the Senate and 107 in the House), a reasonable man might have predicted after the Democratic victory that the New Deal would go on to more reform and continued electoral success. But prediction is a hazardous exercise. In fact, New Deal reform was almost com-
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT
AND THE NEW DEAL •
175
pletely over, and the extraordinary coalition began to come apart at the seams immediately after its most sweeping political victory.
The Deterioration of the Democratic Coalition
In 1937 and 1938 it appeared that FDR had lost his political magic touch. Everything seemed to go wrong at once. Democrats fought Democrats, and Republicans observed the struggles with glee and capitalized upon them in Congress and at the polls. First there was Roosevelt's proposed reorganization of the Supreme
Court and the federal judiciary, which stirred a magnificent row.
Then there was an increasing intrusion of problems of foreign policy into the public consciousness, and the Democratic coalition was divided upon these issues. In the campaigns for the congressional elections of 1938, FDR further inHamed already hot intramural Democratic differences. And all these political troubles took place against a background of further economic difficulty, the recession of 1937-1938. Each of these subjects merits further explanation. The Supreme Court in 1935 and 1936 had declared unconstitutional some critical New Deal measures as well as some progressive legislation enacted by the states. The Court was composed mostly of Republican appointees, and six of the nine justices were over seventy years old. (A popular book in 1936 was
Drew Pearson's and. Robert Allen's Nine Old Men, a vigorous attack on the court.) A group of four justices (Willis Van Devanter, James C. McReynolds, George Sutherland, and Pierce
Butler) consistently wrote decisions that would have pleased Herbert Spencer and other nineteenth-century Social Darwinists. At the other end of the Court were three progressives (Louis D.
Brandeis, Harlan F. Stone, and Benjamin N. Cardozo). The other two justices, Chief Justice Charles Evans Hughes and Owen J.
Roberts, could not easily be classified; sometimes they voted with the conservative four, sometimes with the more progressive three.
Roosevelt had no opportunity to make a Court appointment.
On May 27, 1935, the Court had delivered three blows to the
New Deal, all of them by unanimous decisions. The most important case, Schechter v. United States, declared NRA unconstitutional in its entirety. (A January decision had already declared one aspect of the law contrary to the Constitution.) The Court also declared the Frazier-Lemke Farm Mortgage Act null and void and ruled [hat FDR had illegally removed William E. Humphrey from the Federal Trade Commission. In January 1936, in
176 •
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA, 1919-1941
Butler v. United States, often called the Hoosac Mills case, the
Court held, six to three, that AAA was unconstitutional . In the
Tipaldo case the court by a five-to-four decision struck down a
New York law regulating the hours and wages of women in a decision that was particularly old-fashioned in its legal reasoning and definitions. Roosevelt grumbled privately but restrained himself in his public statements.
Then on February 5, 1937, completely without warning, FDR sent a message to Congress that called for reorganization of the
Supreme Court and the judiciary generally. The effect was electric. Roosevelt asked Congress for legislation empowering him to appoint up to fifty additional federal judges, of whom no more than six would be to the Supreme Court, each new appointment to be made whenever an incumbent judge failed to retire within six months after reaching age seventy. His argument was that age prevented judges from keeping abreast of their work, but it took no special intelligence to see that FDR wanted to make enough new Supreme Court appointments to override the four consistently anti-New Deal justices. The newspapers, which were almost unanimously opposed to the proposal, called it FDR's "court packing bill." Republicans in Congress were opposed almost to a man, as were many Democrats, most of them conservatives. Senate
Republicans made a tactical decision to let their Democratic colleagues carry the fight against the bill.
In May the Senate Judiciary Committee voted to reject the judiciary bill and denounced the whole idea. At the same time,
Justice Van Devanter informed the President that he wanted to retire. This gave FDR his first chance for a Court appointment, but it put him on a spot because before the Court message he had promised the first vacancy to Senate Majority Leader Joseph T.
Robinson of Arkansas, who was then leading the fight for the judiciary proposal against his personal wishes. To appoint Robinson would have been inconsistent with FDR's expressed purposes since the Senator was sixty-five years old. Robinson died of a heart attack in July, and his friends in the Senate thought that he had died from overwork on FDR's project. On the way back from the funeral, they determined to force FDR to accept either a compromise or defeat. FDR compromised and accepted the
Judicial Procedure Reform Act of August 27, 1937, which provided for no new judgeships but did hasten the process of cases involving constitutionality and inhibited the power of judges to issue injunctions that stayed the execution of federal law.
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW DEAL •
177
Roosevelt had to accept much less than he had demanded, but the Court began, even before his defeat, to uphold New Deal legislation. On April 12 it upheld the Wagner Act in three cases, the most important of which was NLRB v. Jones and Laughlin Steel
Company. In West Coast Hotel v. Parrish the Court reversed its
Tipaldo decision and upheld a Washington minimum-wage law.
In August 1937 it approved the Social Security Act. The change in the direction of the Court's decisions has led many historians to say that FDR lost the battle for his judiciary proposal but that he won the war for a more sympathetic Supreme Court. This is a valid interpretation, but it should also be pointed out that the battle decimated his army in Congress and that the army never again won a major legislative campaign. Congress enacted very few reform measures after the Supreme Court uproar. The only important one, the Fair Labor Standards Act, twice needed a discharge petition to get out of the House Rules Committee.
Divisions within Congress on matters of foreign policy were by no means along party lines nor along the same lines that divided progressives from conservatives on domestic issues, and the same was true of the country at large. The terms "isolationist" and
"interventionist," while by no means descriptive, as we shall see in greater detail in the last chapter, were used to label the two main tendencies. Some isolationists supported FDR on domestic issues; some did not. Some interventionists opposed him on domestic affairs; some did not. In order to gain support on foreign policy questions, FDR sometimes had to bargain and compromise on domestic issues. Foreign policy questions thus blurred the New
Deal coalition and led to dissensions within it.
The Democratic party, having within it a greater number of
Catholic voters and a greater number who called themselves liberals than the Republican party, was particularly vulnerable to division upon what policy to follow in connection with the Spanish
Civil War. The Catholic Church hierarchy generally supported
Franco, and the liberals generally supported the Loyalists. Roosevelt, while personally greatly concerned about the strengthening of European fascism by the Spanish war, nevertheless made a decision that in effect aided Franco. The neutrality law in effect when the war began in July 1936 had nothing to say about civil wars, and it thus would have been possible for the United States to have extended aid to the Loyalist Spanish government. Instead,
Roosevelt withheld aid, and in January 1937 got Congress specifically to include civil wars under the neutrality legislation. Inas-
178 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
much as Germany and Italy were giving Franco massive assistance, the American hands-off position played into Franco's hands.
FDR's positions on foreign policy in late 1937 and early 1938 caused further trouble within his party. In an October 1937 speech at Chicago he rather vaguely supported the idea of a
"quarantine" against aggressor nations. Whatever the President had in mind, the idea was far from popular in either party. The sinking of the naval gunboat Panay by Japanese aircraft on December 12, 1937, while the Panay was convoying Standard Oil tankers in the Yangtze River, caused a reaction against Roosevelt's sanctioning of such duty for American naval vessels rather than a demand for action against Japan. (Japan apologized profusely and made financial restitution.) The most serious battle within the New Deal coalition came on an amendment to the
Constitution proposed by Democratic Congressman Louis Ludlow of Indiana. The Ludlow amendment would have required a national referendum before a declaration of war, except in the case of invasion. Roosevelt used great pressure to prevent the amendment's passage, and in January 1938 the House defeated the resolution. But the margin of defeat was only twenty-one votes. Complicating the entire political picture was the dreary fact of economic recession. If the New Deal was a failure at recovery it had little to commend itself to the voters, and the economic situation was bad indeed in 1938. From 1933 to 1937 the economy had significantly improved. By the latter year, the physical volume of industrial production was up to slightly higher than even
1929, and wholesale prices of non-farm products were about what they had been in 1930. Unemployment had declined but by no means as much as was desirable. The Bureau of Labor Statistics estimated unemployment in 1937 at 7,273,000 out of a total labor force of 52,849,000; this was an improvement over the 12,634,000 out of 50,403,000 of 1933, but it was still an unemployment rate of 14 per cent . Farm prices had improved until they were almost up to 1930 levels.
In view of this improvement, economic traditionalists called for a return to more conventional fiscal policies. Secretary of the
Treasury Henry Morgenthau was a particularly influential advocate of balancing the budget. In fiscal 1936 (mid-1935 to mid1936) the federal deficit was $4.3 billion. This fell to $2.7 billion for fiscal 1937 and down further to only $740 million for fiscal
1938, which was almost a balanced budget. Roosevelt had always been uneasy about the growing national debt and in his January
FRANKLIN
D. ROOSEVELT
AND THE NEW DEAL
•
179
1937 budget message had called for a large reduction in federal spending. The cutbacks were effected mostly in smaller WPA payrolls and reduced farm subsidies.
Rather than stimulating business, as traditional economists had predicted, the budget cuts brought on a rather serious recession, beginning in the last quarter of 1937. The physical volume of industrial production fell almost to the level of 1934. Farm prices declined 15 to 20 per cent. Most alarming was the increase in unemployment, 2,637,000 more in 1938 than in 1937, up to 18.7 per cent of the civilian labor force. In 1933 unemployment had averaged 12,634,000 according to BLS estimates, and in 1938 it was
9,910,000, an improvement of only 21.5 per cent. Although federal relief was far more effective than it had been under Hoover, the fact remained that five years of New Deal had not brought about economic recovery. This was a political embarrassment of major proportions for the administration.
For the first few months after the advent of the new depression the President seemed puzzled about what way to turn. Some of his advisers, notably Morgenthau, argued for continued lower spending levels, saying that such policies were necessary for the business community to have faith in the economy's future. Keynesian economists urged a massive resumption of federal spending and a loosening of credit. Some people saw the difficulty as a
"strike of capital," a refusal of businessmen for political reasons to undertake new investments. These people urged FDR to embark upon an antitrust program. Roosevelt failed to make significant economic moves until April 1938. He then urged Congress to increase spending for relief and agriculture and set a major antitrust program going in the Department of Justice. The new head of the Antitrust Division of the Department, Thurmond
Arnold of the Yale Law School, prosecuted vigorously. In June
Congress established the Temporary National Economic Committee, which undertook a vast investigation of the extent of monopoly and the methods used to limit competition.
The year 1939 saw an economic upturn. Physical volume of industrial production rose almost to 1929 levels and unemployment declined by 17.7 per cent. Roosevelt was partly out of the political woods so far as domestic affairs were concerned, although he was more deeply in them in foreign affairs. But until the economy began to improve he was in serious political difficulty, the most serious of his more than twelve years in the White
House.
Annoyed by the refusal of the most conservative Democratic
180 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
members of Congress to go along with White House suggestions,
Roosevelt in June 1938 announced in one of his radio fireside chats what the newspapers promptly called a "purge" in the Democratic congressional primaries. It was highly unusual for a
President to go into a senator's state or a congressman's district and campaign in a primary, but this was precisely what FDR did in certain areas in the summer and fall of 1938. The decision was an abrupt reversal of Roosevelt's usual political acumen. The shrewdest politician of the era made one of the greatest political errors of judgment.
In the first place, FDR backed losers in all but two of the primaries where he publicly expressed a preference. Of all the figures he had marked for defeat, only John O'Connor, a representative from New York City, and A. B. "Happy" Chandler of Kentucky, who opposed Senator Alben W. Barkley, actually lost. Roosevelt's choice against Senator Walter F. George of Georgia never had a chance of winning and came in a poor third on primary day. The very conservative Senator Millard Tydings of Maryland (the same one whom Senator Joseph R. McCarthy would later accuse of being a Communist sympathizer) may have won only because of FDR's opposition, and some argued that Senator Ellison D. "Cotton Ed"
Smith of South Carolina would have lost if it had not been for
Roosevelt's earmarking him for defeat. But, secondly, even in the two cases Roosevelt won he left a bad taste within his own party; those upon whom he had declared open war were not hesitant to reciprocate. Thirdly, other Democratic senators and congressmen, seeing their colleagues survive Rooseveltian opposition and even benefit from it, could more easily be persuaded to oppose the President's wishes in their voting and committee work.
Because of division within Democratic ranks and other factors
-largely the 1938 recession-Republicans in the 1938 elections reversed the fortunes that had worked against them ever since the
1930 elections. They gained eighty seats in the House and eight in the Senate and won several governorships. Ever since the 1938 elections Congress has for all practical purposes been under the control of a coalition of conservatives in both major parties. Most
Republicans vote with this coalition, and enough Democrats, especially those from the South, so that the conservative coalition has never again permitted a burst of progressive legislation such as Congress enacted in 1935. The conservative coalition's strength derives not only from numbers but also from the seniority system, which gives committee chairmanships to members with long tenure. Most Democratic senators and representatives with long
FRANKLIN D. ROOSEVELT AND THE NEW
DEAL·
181
tenure are from Dixie, and many southern members of Congress are fully as conservative as their Republican colleagues.
Thus the elections of 1938 signaled the death of the New Deal.
Closer scrutiny reveals, however, that it was almost dead so far as significant legislation was concerned for the previous two years.
The most important reform measure after the 1936 elections was the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938. The law exempted domestic workers, agricultural labor, and sailors from its provisions, but for all other employees engaged in interstate commerce it set a minimum wage of 25 cents an hour and a maximum work week of forty-four hours. The law provided for gradual increase of the minimum wage to 40 cents an hour in 1945 and a forty-hour work week in 1940. Since the original legislation's passage, the law has been amended a few times to raise the minimum wage. This was not the New Dears first wage-hours legislation. The Walsh-Healy
Act of 1936 had set wage-hours standards for employers who had government contracts. Of lesser stature as reform legislation was the National Housing Act of 1937, which provided for the continuation of public housing and slum clearance undertaken by
PWA. Congress not only failed in 1937 and 1938 to continue reform, it decisively rejected some reform proposals. Senator
Wagner's national health bill of 1938 never got off the ground.
The anti-lynching bill that Wagner co-sponsored with Frederick
Van Nuys of Indiana, which would have allowed the families of lynching victims to sue the county in which the crime had been committed, fell before a southern threat of filibuster. FDR never offered the measure any support.
The New Deal, then, was dead, gone, but not forgotten, roughly five years after it began. Roosevelt was a New Deal president for less than half of his years in office. Roosevelt himself seemed to announce the passing of the New Deal in his message to Congress of January 4, 1939: "We have now passed the period of internal conflict in the launching of our program of social reform. Our full energies may now be released to invigorate the processes of recovery in order to preserve our reforms."
What generalizations can one make about the New Deal, about
Roosevelt, his advisers in the executive branch, and the New
Dealers in Congress? Quite clearly, the New Deal was no grand plan of one man or even any group of men. It was the result of the interplay of political and economic forces, often inconsistent, always sporadic and uneven in development as political balances changed and as the basic conditions altered. Roosevelt was the
182 .
BETWEEN
THE WARS: AMERICA,
1919-1941
central figure, to be sure, but he always had to reckon with the power of men on Capitol Hill, who in turn, as did FDR, had to reckon with the power of their constituents' opinions.
The New Deal's effects are perhaps more important than its methods or the motives of the men who made it. Economically, if the New Deal did not "save" capitalism, it certainly restored it, revived it, and fortified it. Capitalism in America was stronger in late 1938 or early 1939, when the New Deal died, than it had been in 1933, when Roosevelt took the oath of office. Yet, obviously, the New Deal did not bring the economy back to normal. In June
1940, after the fall of France and the Lowlands, during the battles between the RAF and the Luftwaffe in the skies over England, there were still 5,900,000 unemployed workers in the United
States out of a total labor force of 55,700,000, an unemployment rate of 10.6 per cent. It was the war, not the New Deal, that returned prosperity to America, although certainly the New Deal ameliorated economic conditions. The New Deal modified American capitalism-the economy had a closer relationship to federal economic policy than it had previously, and federal law had smoothed the way for the growth of strong labor unions (to be considered in greater detail in the next chapter), which inhibited the policy decisions of capital and management. But, one should remember, the New Deal nationalized no industries nor did it enlarge the government's role in the economy to anything approaching the role of government in democratic and capitalistic nations elsewhere in the world. Indeed, seen from the perspective of
Great Britain, Scandinavia, Australia, France, or Mexico, the New
Deal's reforms were mild and cautious. In terms of governmentprovided services and security guarantees Jor its citizens, the United States, even after the New Deal, was one of the most backward-or most forward if one wishes to apply Herbert SpencerRobert A. Taft-Barry Goldwater standards-of the industrial nations of the world.
The experiences of 1933-1938 greatly altered the facts of political life in the United States. Majority political strength shifted from the Republican to the Democratic party. In 1929 there were more voters registered as Republicans than as Democrats; ten years later the situation was the reverse. But, aside from numbers, the Roosevelt years altered each of the parties. The nature of the Democratic coalition changed as the giant cities shifted more heavily into the Roosevelt camp and as organized labor and the Negro voter enlisted under its banner. Also, liberal intellectuals flocked to the Democratic party in the 1930's as never before.
FRANKLIN
D. ROOSEVELT
AND THE NEW DEAL
•
183
The Democratic party changed considerably in the ten years following 1929; the party of Al Smith bore less resemblance to the party of FDR, Robert Wagner, and Felix Frankfurter than it had to the party of Woodrow Wilson and Colonel House. The
Republican party changed too. Although many, perhaps most, of its leaders even a generation after the New Deal still preferred
Hoover's view of the proper role of the federal government to
Roosevelt's, they seldom dared to say so when they had to face a national election. From 1936 forward, GOP presidential candidates usually adopted a "me-too" stance in their campaigns because the party leaders believed, probably correctly, that an avowed conservative "can't win."
Perhaps it was popular ideology that the New Deal and its background of economic depression changed more than anything else.
Except for issues of foreign policy, a person who died in 1938 would feel at home in political arguments if he could return in the
1960's. Thirty years after the New Deal people were still discussing balanced federal budgets versus deficit financing, "government interference" versus "the rights of labor." Thirty years, even ten or five years, before FDR's inauguration, most such issues and rhetoric would have had a strange ring indeed. For better or for worse, the New Deal period posed the basic questions and provided the usual answers for years to come.
Between the VVars:
A'rrror-Iorr, 1919-1941
David A. Shannon
UNIVERSITY
HOUGHTON
OF
WISCONSIN
MIFFLIN
COMPANY.
Boston
You May Also Find These Documents Helpful
-
o 1) Allowing him to command an army at only 23, which led him to gaining his first triumph something not earned till the end of ones career or not at all…
- 1003 Words
- 5 Pages
Good Essays -
The choices he made had nothing to determine with the outcome, it stand just luck. He worked strong at rising through the military ranks and became a 4 star general. He and his wife set up America's Promise Alliance and as a result of that youth programs and educational resources were provided.…
- 132 Words
- 1 Page
Satisfactory Essays -
He could be brittle and testy in the face of opposition yet his broad knowledge and thoughtful expertise in foreign affairs was valuable.…
- 1339 Words
- 6 Pages
Better Essays -
He starts the pattern off with leadership; you must know where you are going and be able to influence people to work towards a goal without showing authority. Next, there is building authority…
- 617 Words
- 3 Pages
Good Essays -
The website I found is from the heritage foundation, which is a research and educational institution based in Washington D.C. They research, write and cover a variety of American history topics. This website is good for anyone who likes reading about history topics. This article is entitled “Theodore Roosevelt: Progressive Crusader.” The article covers many topics from his early life to his presidency and being a reformer. Everything from his education, family, and accomplishments have been discussed. Most importantly, his time during the progressive era and being a progressive crusader was explored. His accomplishments have been examined in…
- 417 Words
- 2 Pages
Satisfactory Essays -
how he looks up to a figure of authority who is a true and respected man. The next…
- 2695 Words
- 4 Pages
Good Essays -
Some speeches shape nations. Great feats of rhetoric like "I Have a Dream" and the Gettysburg Address seize their readers with intense language and release them with powerful motivation. President Lyndon B. Johnson's 1964 "Great Society" speech directed the American mindset for decades with his potent oration. Somehow, his speech to that University of Michigan crowd remains relevant today. How can a speech made by a barely-remembered president continue to affect American culture fifty years later? Johnson employs a structure of encouragement, warning, and action to construct a strong, moving argument.…
- 581 Words
- 3 Pages
Good Essays -
From his childhood, he was determined, and industrious, and in command of such an unbounded optimism that nothing seemed impossible to him. Foremost in his mind was how best to please his audiences.…
- 849 Words
- 4 Pages
Good Essays -
To what extent did the role of the federal government change under President Theodore Roosevelt in regard to TWO of the following: Labor, Trusts, Conservation, World affairs…
- 318 Words
- 2 Pages
Satisfactory Essays -
exams, which made him to be recognized among students. This made him to be awarded…
- 2120 Words
- 9 Pages
Powerful Essays -
What was the opposition to Roosevelt during his time as President between 1933 and 1945?…
- 1420 Words
- 4 Pages
Good Essays -
about his effort to make his form a vertically integrated one. In spite of its success, it was…
- 6663 Words
- 27 Pages
Satisfactory Essays -
He kept aside the blind beliefs of the community which can be seen by his firm decision of taking…
- 914 Words
- 4 Pages
Good Essays -
in Medical Sciences and on his first job interview, he failed miserably. Why is that so? How can a man of such great intelligence fail? The answer is simple, he did not have the character, drive not to mention personality failed to reach the requirements or he failed to establish a rapport with his future employers. All of this scientific mumbo-jumbo may be confusing you so I will ask you a simple question.…
- 1773 Words
- 8 Pages
Better Essays -
First of all, it’s necessary to notice that a person who links his destiny to politics should possess a streak of political genius and multi-faceted energy. But it’s not enough for an ideal statesperson. An ideal political leader should act honestly and be sustained by ethics. Besides, a good statesman can’t exist without strong character and both conscience and charisma. He needs these basic qualities to gain public adherence.…
- 475 Words
- 2 Pages
Good Essays